The Impact of Individual Investment Behavior for Retirement Welfare: Evidence from the United States and Germany



1970; Merton, 1969, 1971; Samuelson, 1969; Richard, 1975; Kotlikoff and Spivak,
1981). While optimal decision rules were economically logical—such as constant,
age-invariant, proportional asset allocation for intertemporally separable constant
relative risk aversion (CRRA) utility—they often failed to mirror actual behavior.
The challenge posed to all researchers has since been to relax various rigorous
assumptions that do not hold in reality, such as intertemporally separable utility,
infinite time horizon, or perfect markets, where the individual can span all assets
including human capital, or the absence of borrowing or short-selling restrictions.

A growing body of research now offers optimal decision rules with increasing
relaxation of such assumptions. Based on realistically calibrated consumption-
saving-asset allocation intertemporal optimization models, decisions depend on
gender, education, age, human capital (i.e., the stock and riskiness of labor/pension
income and pension age), wealth, taxation, transaction costs, and the likelihood of
binding borrowing or short-selling restrictions.8 A detailed discussion of the specific
impact of these factors based on the normative model used here is given in section
3.3.

2.2.2 Individual Welfare Considerations

Section 2.1 presented evidence that individual investment behavior differs according
to various factors such as age, wealth, income, and gender. Not surprisingly, different
investment strategies lead to different wealth outcomes—for example, wealth at the
beginning of retirement. More conservative investment strategies result in lower
expected final wealth; for example, the simulation by Watson and McNaughton
(2007) shows for Australian investors that women, being more-risk averse, end up
with lower expected retirement wealth.

8 See Zeldes (1989); Deaton (1991); Carroll (1992, 1997); Hubbard, Skinner, and Zeldes
(1994, 1995); Heaton and Lucas (1997, 2000); Laibson, Repetto, and Tobacman (1998);
Viceira (2001); Campbell and Viceira (2002); Blake, Cairns, and Dowd (2003); Gomes
and Michaelides (2003, 2005); Haliassos and Michaelides (2003); Dammon, Spatt, and
Zhang (2004); Lachance (2004); Cocco (2005); Cocco, Gomes, and Maenhout (2005);
Davis, Kubler, and Willen (2005); Yao and Zhang (2005); Horneff, Maurer, and Stamos
(2006); Post, Gründl, and Schmeiser (2006); and Polkovnichenko (2007).



More intriguing information

1. INSTITUTIONS AND PRICE TRANSMISSION IN THE VIETNAMESE HOG MARKET
2. The name is absent
3. Cyber-pharmacies and emerging concerns on marketing drugs Online
4. The name is absent
5. The Formation of Wenzhou Footwear Clusters: How Were the Entry Barriers Overcome?
6. SME'S SUPPORT AND REGIONAL POLICY IN EU - THE NORTE-LITORAL PORTUGUESE EXPERIENCE
7. The name is absent
8. Palkkaneuvottelut ja työmarkkinat Pohjoismaissa ja Euroopassa
9. Critical Race Theory and Education: Racism and antiracism in educational theory and praxis David Gillborn*
10. The name is absent
11. The name is absent
12. The name is absent
13. The name is absent
14. STIMULATING COOPERATION AMONG FARMERS IN A POST-SOCIALIST ECONOMY: LESSONS FROM A PUBLIC-PRIVATE MARKETING PARTNERSHIP IN POLAND
15. NATIONAL PERSPECTIVE
16. The name is absent
17. The name is absent
18. The name is absent
19. The name is absent
20. Dual Track Reforms: With and Without Losers