Imperfect competition and congestion in the City



dgi(wi) -1
dwi


dPw

pw + gi(wi) - Wi - c - hPW]     = 0.

dwi

Substituting the expressions (34) and (33), the first-order condition, at the
symmetric candidate equilibrium reduces to:

Γμd h + Λd 1

Lμw y ' nd n


(pe - We


( n1Й + 1 + λw 1
∖ n / ∕         μw n

- c - Λh 2 ¢ ɪ n1
n f μw n


( n 1
\ n

=0.


(36)


Therefore, the candidate equilibrium price is given by the solution of (36):

pe = c + —+ we + d + μw)
n

where b = yMah+ad+âw] 6and where Λh = αhδ N a.

Proposition 4 With congestion but without congestion pricing, there exists a
unique symmetric Nash equilibrium in prices and wages given by:

e   I Л I e∣∕d∣ wʌ n I δ N "2

p — c +    + w + μ + μ J i + b          (37)

Proof. See Appendix C. ■

Note that without congestion, the equilibrium price reduces to equation (17).
With congestion, there are two additional positive terms in the RHS. First the
marginal production cost is now c
+ Λh /n + we and contains a congestion term
translating the increased cost of intermediate deliveries. The second term is
related to the congestion created by shopping, commuting and intermediate
delivery traffic and represents the increased market power effect.

The markup (pe - c - Λh /n - we) now has two components. The first one
is the product/wage heterogeneity term (proportional to
(μd + μw)), as in the
non-congested case. The second term, represents the externality due to conges-
tion7 As discussed, congestion reduces the incentive to cut prices, and therefore,
increases equilibrium prices. This may explain why shops often lobby against
policy measures which aim to improve traffic conditions in general although a
firm individually will be in favour of local improvements of traffic, i.e. measures
which improve the accessability to.workers and consumers.

The short run equilibrium profit (see 35 and 37 is:

N δ αN 2

πe(s) = d + μw) (n-1) + s J - (F + S)         (38)

which is an increasing function of the congestion level.

6 Note than when κ =1, αb = α.

7The total cost is TC = αNte = αN Çt + δα-N^ . Therefore the externality, which is the
difference between the marginal cost and the average cost is equal to:
δα2= α (te t) .

17



More intriguing information

1. Understanding the (relative) fall and rise of construction wages
2. National urban policy responses in the European Union: Towards a European urban policy?
3. The name is absent
4. Non-farm businesses local economic integration level: the case of six Portuguese small and medium-sized Markettowns• - a sector approach
5. Spectral density bandwith choice and prewightening in the estimation of heteroskadasticity and autocorrelation consistent covariance matrices in panel data models
6. Institutions, Social Norms, and Bargaining Power: An Analysis of Individual Leisure Time in Couple Households
7. Constructing the Phylomemetic Tree Case of Study: Indonesian Tradition-Inspired Buildings
8. The name is absent
9. The name is absent
10. Valuing Access to our Public Lands: A Unique Public Good Pricing Experiment
11. A Theoretical Growth Model for Ireland
12. THE INTERNATIONAL OUTLOOK FOR U.S. TOBACCO
13. On Social and Market Sanctions in Deterring non Compliance in Pollution Standards
14. The name is absent
15. The name is absent
16. Økonomisk teorihistorie - Overflødig information eller brugbar ballast?
17. Evaluating the Success of the School Commodity Food Program
18. The name is absent
19. A Study of Adult 'Non-Singers' In Newfoundland
20. Program Semantics and Classical Logic