The name is absent



The key point is that displacement of labor with
a labor-saving technology in a given industry would
only decrease labor’s relative share in that industry if
elasticity of substitution is greater than one. This is
precisely what Lianos [11] found to be the case for
the U.S. agricultural sector in the aggregate since
World War II.

Ferguson and Moroney [4], however, found that
despite adoption of labor-saving technology in most
industries in the U.S. manufacturing sector, capital
deepening accompanied by an elasticity of factor
substitution less than one resulted in an increase in
labor’s relative share. This implies that there has been
greater ease of substitution of capital for labor in the
U.S. agricultural sector than in the manufacturing
sector. Hence, in spite of the introduction of labor-
saving technology, labor’s relative share increased in
the industrial sector. In the agricultural sector,
however, labor was more easily displaced by capital-
intensive, labor-saving technology and consequently,
labor’s relative share declined.

U.S. COTTON LABOR’S RELATIVE SHARE:
AN EMPIRICAL EXAMPLE

Rather extensive investigations [4, 9, 10] have
been made of changes in factor shares for selected
industries within the U.S. manufacturing sector. This
has not been the case for the crop or livestock
components of the U.S. agricultural sector.

Mechanization of cotton production in the U.S.
has been quite rapid. Cotton production prior to the
post World War II period was one of the most
labor-intensive major crops. The majority of labor
input for cotton production during the pre-war
period was required for the harvesting operation.2
Introduction of mechanical cotton harvesters after
World War II reduced labor requirements in harvest-
ing by approximately 95 percent [12].

Rate of adoption of mechanical harvesters was
quite rapid. In 1946 only one percent of U.S.-grown
cotton was mechanically harvested. By 1970 virtually
all (97 percent) cotton produced in the U.S. was
picked mechanically.

For most family and hired workers who had been
employed in cotton production this meant the end of
agricultural employment, and eventually compelled
many to go to towns and cities, (mostly in the North)
to live and seek employment. The resulting rural-
urban migration led to difficult socio-economic
adjustment problems for both migrants and affected
cities. For cotton farmers, the capital-intensive nature
of the new technology drastically altered farm organi-
zation and operation.

The question addressed in this section, however,
is: What happened to labor’s relative share within the
cotton sector? Real farm wages in the South in-
creased 50 percent from 1952 to 1969, the period of
the most rapid rate of adoption of cotton pickers,
while man-hours devoted to cotton production fell
over 80 percent. Furthermore, real value of cotton
production, including acreage diversion transfer pay-
ments, also fell by nearly 60 percent. Moreover,
labor’s relative share (S
l) in the cotton sector fell
from 39 percent in 1952 to 22 percent in 1969, a
decline of 44 percent (Table 2).

The mathematical derivation in the previous
section suggests that, given a labor-saving tech-
nological change in the cotton sector which displaces

TABLE 2. WAGE RATES, MAN-HOURS, VALUE
OF PRODUCTION AND LABOR’S
RELATIVE SHARE FOR U.S. COTTON
PRODUCTION, 1952-1969

Year

Real Wage ,
Rate∕Hour^∙'

Man-hours
Cotton-Labor
(millions)

Real Value

Output Includ-
ing Acreage
Diversion Payments
(S millions)k/

Labor j
Shared

<SL>

1952

0.5710

1655

2446.4

0.3863

1953

0.5978

1609

2736.8

0.3515

1954

0.5905

1269

2407.3

0.3113

1955

0.6043

1235

2655.2

0.2811

1956

0.6335

1074

2389.8

0.2847

1957

0.6253

818

1787.8

0.2861

1958

0.6220

769

2015.1

0.2374

1959

0.6330

911

2586.2

0.2230

1960

0.6433

831

2861.7

0.1868

1961

0.6540

772

2677.6

0.1886

1962

0.6603

679

2648.6

0.1693

1963

0.6720

647

2816.0

0.1544

1964

0.6958

573

2614.0

0.1525

1965

0.7155

483

2212.3

0.1562

1966

0.7405

309

1324.6

0.1727

1967

0.7935

242

1397.3

0.1374

1968

0.8308

275

1446.7

0.1579

1969

0.8615

279

1045.2

0.2230

SOURCE: United States Department of Agriculture publica-
tions [16, 17, 18].

aAverage of four major cotton regions: South Atlantic,
East South Central, West South Central and Pacific. Deflated
by Prices Paid by Farmers Index, 1947-49 = 100.

^Deflated by Wholesale Price Index, 1947-49 = 100.
Price used is a composite of market price and support price
based on cotton program participation.

cColumn one multiplied by column two divided by
column three.

2The other labor-intensive activity was “chopping” cotton. This operation has also been largely mechanized.

139



More intriguing information

1. The Advantage of Cooperatives under Asymmetric Cost Information
2. TOWARD CULTURAL ONCOLOGY: THE EVOLUTIONARY INFORMATION DYNAMICS OF CANCER
3. The name is absent
4. AN EMPIRICAL INVESTIGATION OF THE PRODUCTION EFFECTS OF ADOPTING GM SEED TECHNOLOGY: THE CASE OF FARMERS IN ARGENTINA
5. The Composition of Government Spending and the Real Exchange Rate
6. Fiscal Reform and Monetary Union in West Africa
7. Strengthening civil society from the outside? Donor driven consultation and participation processes in Poverty Reduction Strategies (PRSP): the Bolivian case
8. Forecasting Financial Crises and Contagion in Asia using Dynamic Factor Analysis
9. The name is absent
10. The name is absent
11. The name is absent
12. La mobilité de la main-d'œuvre en Europe : le rôle des caractéristiques individuelles et de l'hétérogénéité entre pays
13. Licensing Schemes in Endogenous Entry
14. Critical Race Theory and Education: Racism and antiracism in educational theory and praxis David Gillborn*
15. Running head: CHILDREN'S ATTRIBUTIONS OF BELIEFS
16. Learning and Endogenous Business Cycles in a Standard Growth Model
17. The name is absent
18. Public-Private Partnerships in Urban Development in the United States
19. The name is absent
20. Public Debt Management in Brazil