The name is absent



labor is more limited, labor’s relative share, even
though a labor-saving technology is being adopted,
can increase.

U.S. cotton production has been rapidly
mechanized in the post World War II period. Given
the relative ease of substitution of capital for labor
(σ> 1) and the labor-saving bias
(β> 1) of modern
capital inputs such as cotton pickers, U.S. cotton
labor’s relative share of output has tended to decline
since World War II.

Knowledge of elasticity of factor substitution
can be especially important for policy-makers in
developing economies where labor tends to be rela-
tively abundant. If elasticity of factor substitution is
less than one, then adoption of a labor-saving
technology can actually lead to an increase in labor’s
relative share. However, if elasticity of factor sub-
stitution is greater than one, adoption of a labor-
saving technology will not only displace labor but
moreover labor’s relative share will decline.

One concluding caveat is in order. A decline in
labor’s relative share in a particular industry, or
within a given sector, does not necessarily mean that
those workers who left the industry or sector are
worse off. Workers may be able to obtain employ-
ment in another sector. Furthermore, a decline in
labor’s relative share implies only that the portion of
the value of total output going to labor employed in a
given sector or industry has declined. The labor share
analysis presented in this article is based only on
functional distribution of income—it does not explain
personal income distribution.

REFERENCES

[1] Allen, R. G. D. Mathematical Analysis for Economists, New York: St. Martin’s Press, 1962.

[2] Blakley, Leo V. “Quantitative Relationships in the Cotton Economy with Implications for Economic
Policy,” Technical Bulletin T-95, Oklahoma State University, Agricultural Experiment Station, 1962.

[3] Day, Richard H. “The Economics of Technological Change and the Demise of the Sharecropper,” American
Economic Review,
Volume 57, 1967, pp. 427-449.

[4] Ferguson, C. E. and John R. Moroney. “The Sources of Change in Labor’s Relative Share: A Neoclassical
Analysis,”
Southern Economic Journal, Volume 35, 1969, pp. 308-322.

[5] Hayami, Yujiro and Vernon W. Ruttan. Agricultural Development, An International Perspective, Baltimore:
Johns Hopkins Press, 1971.

[6] Hicks, John R. The Theory of Wages, London: MacMillan and Co., Ltd., Second Edition, 1963.

[7] Johnson, Harry. The Two Sector Model of General Equilibrium, Chicago: Aldine Atherton, 1971.

[8] Kaneda, Hiromitsu. “Regional Patterns of Technical Change in U.S. Agriculture, 1950-1963,” Journal of
Farm Economics,
Volume 49, 1967, pp. 199-212.

[9] Keynes, John M. “Relative Movements of Real Wages and Output,” Economic Journal, Volume 49,1939,
pp. 34-65.

[10] Kravis, Irving B. “Relative Income Shares in Fact and Theory,” American Economic Review, Volume 49,
1959, pp. 917-949.

[11] Lianos, Theodore P. “The Relative Share of Labor in United States Agriculture, 1949-1968,” American
Journal of Agricultural Economics,
Volume 53, 1971, pp. 411-422.

[12] Maier, Frank H. “An Economic Analysis of Adoption of the Mechanical Cotton Picker,” Ph.D. thesis,
University of Chicago, 1969.

[13] Martin, Marshall A. “The Income Distribution Impacts of the Adoption of Mechanical Harvesting of Cotton
in the United States,” M.S. thesis, Purdue University, 1972.

[14] Ruttan, Vernon W. and Thomas T. Stout. “Regional Differences in Factor Shares in American Agriculture:
1925-1957,”
Journal of Farm Economics, Volume 42, 1960, pp. 52-68.

[15] Tyrchniewicz, Edward W. and G. E. Schuh. “Econometric Analysis of the Agricultural Labor Market,”
AmericanJournal OfAgriculturalEconomics, Volume 51, 1969, pp. 770-787.

[16] U.S. Department of Agriculture. Agricultural Statistics, Washington, D.C., various issues.

[17] U.S. Department of Agriculture. Farm Labor, Washington, D.C., various issues.

[18] U.S. Department of Agriculture. Statistics on Cotton and Related Data 1930-1967, Bulletin No. 417,
Washington, D.C., 1968.

[19] Wallace, T. D. and Dale M. Hoover. “Income Effects of Innovation: The Case of Labor in Agriculture,”
Journal of Farm Economics, Volume 48, 1966, pp. 325-336.

141



More intriguing information

1. The name is absent
2. Bridging Micro- and Macro-Analyses of the EU Sugar Program: Methods and Insights
3. Public-private sector pay differentials in a devolved Scotland
4. Cultural Diversity and Human Rights: a propos of a minority educational reform
5. The name is absent
6. Optimal Vehicle Size, Haulage Length, and the Structure of Transport Costs
7. The name is absent
8. The name is absent
9. Perceived Market Risks and Strategic Risk Management of Food Manufactures: Empirical Results from the German Brewing Industry
10. The name is absent
11. Structural Conservation Practices in U.S. Corn Production: Evidence on Environmental Stewardship by Program Participants and Non-Participants
12. The name is absent
13. On the Real Exchange Rate Effects of Higher Electricity Prices in South Africa
14. Errors in recorded security prices and the turn-of-the year effect
15. Secondary stress in Brazilian Portuguese: the interplay between production and perception studies
16. Does South Africa Have the Potential and Capacity to Grow at 7 Per Cent?: A Labour Market Perspective
17. Ability grouping in the secondary school: attitudes of teachers of practically based subjects
18. Modelling the health related benefits of environmental policies - a CGE analysis for the eu countries with gem-e3
19. Do Decision Makers' Debt-risk Attitudes Affect the Agency Costs of Debt?
20. Developmental Robots - A New Paradigm