%3D3 œ #3Dz3 • (1 - "3P8/!3)[P8 - 1/("з — #3)],
œ #3DZ3 • (1 - %3Q)[p8 - 1∕("3- #3)], (12)
where !3 is the budget share of good i. Again, in comParison with the semilog demand
system where quality enters in a similar way (Table 1), the semilog own quality elasticity
has additional terms involving %3Q and ("3 -#3), which gives increased flexibility.
The Marshallian cross-quality slopes are given by
'X3∕'Z4 œ #4Dp8("3 - #3 )e# ' !# P
œ#4Dp48(x3 -"3M),
and the Marshallian cross-quality elasticities are
` = 'X3 . z4
'■ ■ ´ ∂z2 X3
œ #4Dz4p8 • (1 - "3P8/!3).
œ#4Dz4p48 •(1 -%3Q). (13)
Similarly to the price effects, the cross-quality effect in the DS system has an eXtra term,
(1 - %37), relative to the semilog system (Table 1). Combining (12) and (13) with (11),
the full set of relationships between quality, price, and income effects within a given
demand function are
More intriguing information
1. Luce Irigaray and divine matter2. The name is absent
3. An alternative way to model merit good arguments
4. Transport system as an element of sustainable economic growth in the tourist region
5. Declining Discount Rates: Evidence from the UK
6. FASTER TRAINING IN NONLINEAR ICA USING MISEP
7. The Demand for Specialty-Crop Insurance: Adverse Selection and Moral Hazard
8. PER UNIT COSTS TO OWN AND OPERATE FARM MACHINERY
9. Evidence of coevolution in multi-objective evolutionary algorithms
10. Herman Melville and the Problem of Evil