%3D3 œ #3Dz3 • (1 - "3P8/!3)[P8 - 1/("з — #3)],
œ #3DZ3 • (1 - %3Q)[p8 - 1∕("3- #3)], (12)
where !3 is the budget share of good i. Again, in comParison with the semilog demand
system where quality enters in a similar way (Table 1), the semilog own quality elasticity
has additional terms involving %3Q and ("3 -#3), which gives increased flexibility.
The Marshallian cross-quality slopes are given by
'X3∕'Z4 œ #4Dp8("3 - #3 )e# ' !# P
œ#4Dp48(x3 -"3M),
and the Marshallian cross-quality elasticities are
` = 'X3 . z4
'■ ■ ´ ∂z2 X3
œ #4Dz4p8 • (1 - "3P8/!3).
œ#4Dz4p48 •(1 -%3Q). (13)
Similarly to the price effects, the cross-quality effect in the DS system has an eXtra term,
(1 - %37), relative to the semilog system (Table 1). Combining (12) and (13) with (11),
the full set of relationships between quality, price, and income effects within a given
demand function are
More intriguing information
1. The name is absent2. The name is absent
3. The name is absent
4. Perfect Regular Equilibrium
5. Changing spatial planning systems and the role of the regional government level; Comparing the Netherlands, Flanders and England
6. Higher education funding reforms in England: the distributional effects and the shifting balance of costs
7. The bank lending channel of monetary policy: identification and estimation using Portuguese micro bank data
8. News Not Noise: Socially Aware Information Filtering
9. Government spending composition, technical change and wage inequality
10. Valuing Farm Financial Information