The first-differentiated Stone's index, ∆ logP* may be decomposed into three components:
n nn
(9) ∆ log P * = ∑ w. ∙∆ log pj + ∑ ∆ w ■ log pj - ∑ ∆ w ∙∆ log pj .
j =1j =1j =1
The second and third term are likely to be quite small since, in the context of time-series data,
shares usually do not change much from one observation to the next (Alston and Chalfant).
Substituting the first term of ∆ logP * from Equation (9) into the first-differentiated LA/AIDS in
Equation (8) yields
(10) ∆wi≈∑n γij∆logpj+βi[∆logX-∑n wj∆logpj].
j =1j =1
Equation (10) is similar to the Rotterdam model. Any difference is in the specification of the
income term. Theil and Clements (1987) refer to DQ in Equation (1) as a finite change version of
the Divisia volume index (Alston and Chalfant). It is approximately equal to
(11) DQ* =∆ log X -∆ log P ° ,
n
where ∆ log P ° = ∑ wj ■ ∆ log pj, which is similar to the first-differentiated Stone’s price index
j=1
in Equation (9). Substituting DQ* for DQ, the Rotterdam model is re-specified as follows
More intriguing information
1. The name is absent2. Testing for One-Factor Models versus Stochastic Volatility Models
3. The name is absent
4. Public infrastructure capital, scale economies and returns to variety
5. Imperfect competition and congestion in the City
6. Cancer-related electronic support groups as navigation-aids: Overcoming geographic barriers
7. Equity Markets and Economic Development: What Do We Know
8. Gianluigi Zenti, President, Academia Barilla SpA - The Changing Consumer: Demanding but Predictable
9. The name is absent
10. The fundamental determinants of financial integration in the European Union