DEMAND FOR MEAT AND FISH PRODUCTS IN KOREA



The first-differentiated Stone's index, logP* may be decomposed into three components:

n  nn

(9)           log P * =w. ∙∆ log pj + w log pj -w ∙∆ log pj .

j =1j =1j =1

The second and third term are likely to be quite small since, in the context of time-series data,
shares usually do not change much from one observation to the next (Alston and Chalfant).

Substituting the first term of logP * from Equation (9) into the first-differentiated LA/AIDS in

Equation (8) yields

(10)           win γijlogpj+βi[logX-n wjlogpj].

j =1j =1

Equation (10) is similar to the Rotterdam model. Any difference is in the specification of the
income term. Theil and Clements (1987) refer to
DQ in Equation (1) as a finite change version of
the Divisia volume index
(Alston and Chalfant). It is approximately equal to

(11)          DQ* =∆ log X -∆ log P ° ,

n

where log P ° = wj ■ ∆ log pj, which is similar to the first-differentiated Stone’s price index
j=1

in Equation (9). Substituting DQ* for DQ, the Rotterdam model is re-specified as follows



More intriguing information

1. Personal Income Tax Elasticity in Turkey: 1975-2005
2. Pass-through of external shocks along the pricing chain: A panel estimation approach for the euro area
3. Consumption Behaviour in Zambia: The Link to Poverty Alleviation?
4. The name is absent
5. Permanent and Transitory Policy Shocks in an Empirical Macro Model with Asymmetric Information
6. New urban settlements in Belarus: some trends and changes
7. The name is absent
8. The Role of area-yield crop insurance program face to the Mid-term Review of Common Agricultural Policy
9. Intertemporal Risk Management Decisions of Farmers under Preference, Market, and Policy Dynamics
10. Moffett and rhetoric