Monetary Discretion, Pricing Complementarity and Dynamic Multiple Equilibria



3 Equilibrium with homogeneous policy

We begin by studying the nature of equilibrium price-setting (p0,t) given an arbitrary ac-
tion by the monetary authority and given perfect foresight. We assume that the monetary
authority adopts a policy rule of the form

Mt = mtP0,t-1 ,                                  (16)

where mt is viewed as the policy variable. That is, the money supply is proportional to
the prices that adjusting firms set one period ago with a constant of proportionality
mt .
We call this a homogenous monetary policy rule. This form of monetary accommodation
of past nominal variables is characteristic of optimal monetary policy under discretion, for
the following reason. The monetary authority is concerned about the real variables that
enter in private agents’ utility. It takes past prices as given, and there is no mechanism by
which the level of nominal predetermined prices necessarily constrains the behavior of a
discretionary policymaker.5 Thus, if we viewed
M instead of m as the policy instrument,
we would find that the optimizing monetary authority adjusted
Mt proportionally to
P1,t, just as is specified in (16). It will economize slightly on notation and computation
to view
mt as the policy instrument, and there is no loss in generality. In a discretionary
equilibrium,
mt will be chosen to maximize welfare; in this section mt is arbitrary.6

A homogenous money supply rule means that the future money supply depends on
the price set by adjusting firms today,

Mt+1 = mt+1P0,t.

Consequently, under homogeneous policy and using the preferences introduced above,
it follows from the efficient price-setting condition (11) that the nominal price set by
adjusting firms (
P0,t) satisfies

Po,t =    χ ((1 - θt,t+ι) mtPι,t + θt,t+1mt+1P0,t)                 (17)

ε - 1

in equilibrium. The derivation of (17) from (11) involves (i) using the fact that nominal
marginal cost is Ψ
t = Ptχct given the specific utility assumption; (ii) using the money de-
mand relationship (
Mt = Ptct); and (iii) imposing the homogenous form of the monetary

5 The word “necessarily” appears because one could construct non-Markov equilibria in which all
agents agreed that P
1,t did constrain the monetary authority. See previous footnote. We do not study
such equilibria.

6By contrast, under commitment, the monetary authority commits not to respond to P1,t, and the
choice is over sequences of M
t . King and Wolman (1999) study optimal policy with commitment in the
model used here.

13



More intriguing information

1. Climate change, mitigation and adaptation: the case of the Murray–Darling Basin in Australia
2. National curriculum assessment: how to make it better
3. The mental map of Dutch entrepreneurs. Changes in the subjective rating of locations in the Netherlands, 1983-1993-2003
4. Backpropagation Artificial Neural Network To Detect Hyperthermic Seizures In Rats
5. A Duality Approach to Testing the Economic Behaviour of Dairy-Marketing Co-operatives: The Case of Ireland
6. Unilateral Actions the Case of International Environmental Problems
7. Foreign Direct Investment and the Single Market
8. DETERMINANTS OF FOOD AWAY FROM HOME AMONG AFRICAN-AMERICANS
9. Mergers under endogenous minimum quality standard: a note
10. The name is absent
11. The growing importance of risk in financial regulation
12. The Advantage of Cooperatives under Asymmetric Cost Information
13. Are class size differences related to pupils’ educational progress and classroom processes? Findings from the Institute of Education Class Size Study of children aged 5-7 Years
14. NATURAL RESOURCE SUPPLY CONSTRAINTS AND REGIONAL ECONOMIC ANALYSIS: A COMPUTABLE GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM APPROACH
15. Publication of Foreign Exchange Statistics by the Central Bank of Chile
16. The name is absent
17. The name is absent
18. The name is absent
19. The name is absent
20. Alzheimer’s Disease and Herpes Simplex Encephalitis