On the Relation between Robust and Bayesian Decision Making



When Ωs contains the states of the world in a primitive sense, then equation
(3) implies that the decision maker has a preference for global robustness, as an
action
x is evaluated with respect to all possible outcomes. For the case where
Ωs indexes a set of probability distributions (economic models), equation (3)
allows for a preference for local robustness, as the decision maker seeks only to
be robust with respect to models contained in
Ωs.

It is useful to rewrite the robust decision problem as follows:

min R(x    with

c Ω

I

R(x) ∑L(x,si)I(x,si)                      (4)

i=l

where I(x,Si) is an indicator function that is equal to one if Si is a maximizer
of
L(x,si) and that is equal to zero otherwise.2 Rewriting the robust objective
in this way helps to highlight the relation to the Bayesian problem (2).

The indicator functions appearing in (4) look almost like ’prior probabilities’
of the robust decision maker. These ’robust priors’ put all probability weight on
the worst state associated with a given decision
x. Since this worst state may
shift with
x, the ’prior’ of the robust decision maker may shift with the chosen
decision. This is a major di
fference to Bayesian priors.

Given the previous observation, there exists an immediate equivalence be-
tween robust and Bayesian decisions, as pointed out by Chamberlain (2000)
and Hansen et al. (2002): if the Bayesian’s priors put all probability weight on
the worst state associated with the robust decision, then the optimal Bayesian
decision is identical to the robust decision. Note, however, that these priors
need not be rational from a Bayesian perspective.

Instead of choosing the Bayesian’s priors, this paper seeks to choose an
objective function for the Bayesian problem to achieve an equivalence between
the optimal Bayesian and robust decisions that holds (almost) independent from
the prior probabilities assigned by the Bayesian. This is done in the next section.

2If there are several maximizers I define the indicator function to be 1 only for the state
with the lowest index
i.



More intriguing information

1. Fiscal federalism and Fiscal Autonomy: Lessons for the UK from other Industrialised Countries
2. Gender and aquaculture: sharing the benefits equitably
3. Sectoral specialisation in the EU a macroeconomic perspective
4. A Review of Kuhnian and Lakatosian “Explanations” in Economics
5. MANAGEMENT PRACTICES ON VIRGINIA DAIRY FARMS
6. Target Acquisition in Multiscale Electronic Worlds
7. Literary criticism as such can perhaps be called the art of rereading.
8. The technological mediation of mathematics and its learning
9. A Rare Presentation of Crohn's Disease
10. Novelty and Reinforcement Learning in the Value System of Developmental Robots
11. ARE VOLATILITY EXPECTATIONS CHARACTERIZED BY REGIME SHIFTS? EVIDENCE FROM IMPLIED VOLATILITY INDICES
12. Empirically Analyzing the Impacts of U.S. Export Credit Programs on U.S. Agricultural Export Competitiveness
13. The name is absent
14. The bank lending channel of monetary policy: identification and estimation using Portuguese micro bank data
15. Education and Development: The Issues and the Evidence
16. Research Design, as Independent of Methods
17. Opciones de política económica en el Perú 2011-2015
18. The name is absent
19. Industrial districts, innovation and I-district effect: territory or industrial specialization?
20. The name is absent