Problems of operationalizing the concept of a cost-of-living index



increasing (in elements of q), quasi-concave9 (to establish an unequivocal
maximum), and twice continuously differentiable function over all parts of
its domain. These assumptions are known as “regularity conditions” and
they are reconcilable only with a limited number of functional forms so that
not all imaginable functions are eligible for representing
f (q).

For the COLI theory it suffices to postulate such quite general proper-
ties of a utility function f (
q), however, for the SIA it is necessary to be
more specific regarding the functional form of f (
q).10 The problem with
utility maximising is that we cannot be sure whether or not households in
fact perform this optimisation exercise in their decision making.11 The SIA
rationale, however, decisively rests on the assumption that observed expen-
ditures are resulting from utility maximisation. More specific it is assumed
that the scalar product
p(qs = ɪbPisQis (^ = 1,. . . , ^ and s = 0, t) is equal
to the value of the cost function12 c (
ps, us) in both periods s = 0 and s = t.
Interestingly from the mere
definition of c as minimum costs (expenditure)
follows that
ptqo c (pt,uo) and p(1qi c (po, ut) and therefore

pL = pqo c(ps,uo) = c(pt,uo)
ot p0qo_ p0qo      c (po,uo)

(4)

(5)


and

pp = p⅛ pq = c(p1ut)
ot poq⅛ ~ c (po,ui)    c (po,ui).

In each equation the rightmost term is a COLI referring to a utility level of
u
o and ut respectively.13 It is common practice to refer not only to the same

9This is a curvature condition for f (q). A concave utility function means somewhat
simplified that average quantities of all goods are preferred to extreme or one-sided con-
sumption (0% or 100% of the budget devoted to one specific good).

10We consider these additional assumptions in sec. 2.3.

11It is indeed an advantage the econometric demand-system-approach (DSA) enjoys over
the SIA that empirical results (like ours) indicating a poor goodness of fit of the respective
models to data may be taken as a hint that household possibly are not acting as utility
maximiser so that the theoretic assumptions may not be realistic.

12That is the minimum costs (expenditure) of achieving a utility level us under a pre-
vailing price vector ps (or to put it differently we chose that very vector
q of quantities for
which the expenditure
q,ps under the price regime of period s is a minimum). A unique
value c of c
(ps, us) requires that the above mentioned conditions are met concerning the
utility function
us = f (qs) from which the function c(ps,us) is derived.

13This is in the literature sometimes called Laspeyres-KonUs and Paasche-KonUs (price)



More intriguing information

1. Økonomisk teorihistorie - Overflødig information eller brugbar ballast?
2. Placentophagia in Nonpregnant Nulliparous Mice: A Genetic Investigation1
3. Spatial patterns in intermunicipal Danish commuting
4. Workforce or Workfare?
5. Death as a Fateful Moment? The Reflexive Individual and Scottish Funeral Practices
6. Types of Tax Concessions for Promoting Investment in Free Economic and Trade Areas
7. Education as a Moral Concept
8. The Formation of Wenzhou Footwear Clusters: How Were the Entry Barriers Overcome?
9. Retirement and the Poverty of the Elderly in Portugal
10. Bird’s Eye View to Indonesian Mass Conflict Revisiting the Fact of Self-Organized Criticality
11. Environmental Regulation, Market Power and Price Discrimination in the Agricultural Chemical Industry
12. HACCP AND MEAT AND POULTRY INSPECTION
13. An alternative way to model merit good arguments
14. The name is absent
15. Optimal Rent Extraction in Pre-Industrial England and France – Default Risk and Monitoring Costs
16. The Variable-Rate Decision for Multiple Inputs with Multiple Management Zones
17. On the Desirability of Taxing Charitable Contributions
18. Discourse Patterns in First Language Use at Hcme and Second Language Learning at School: an Ethnographic Approach
19. The name is absent
20. The name is absent