Problems of operationalizing the concept of a cost-of-living index



utility function f (q) but also to same value и of this function (u = f (q)) in
both numerator and denominator of the COLI (price) index which thus is
defined as equation (1) in the introduction. It is important to note that the
assumption that households utility maximisation on the part of the house-
holds is crucial. Otherwise we could not equate
p(qs = c (ps,us) and bring
the observed indices
Pl and Pp into play and relate them to the unobserved
COLI. Once utility maximisation does not take place a superlative index will
no longer approximate the COLI.

Ad 3: In order to define the budget constraint (or isocost plane) it is
necessary to specify how total consumption expenditure14
M is related to
income15 and the commodity prices p
ɪ,.. . , p^ are generally assumed as being
determined exogenously. Households are assumed to be price takers which
means prices are given, independent of quantities purchased and the same
for all households.16 Also M is given which means that we do not explain a
household’s time allocation and labour supply on the basis of decisions over
leisure time
tL and working hours tw with reference to a utility function
f
(q, t) where t = tL + tw.

Along with the above mentioned regularity conditions concerning f (q)
such assumptions are needed in order to have a linear budget constraint
otherwise we would run into difficulties establishing an optimum as a unique
tangency point of the isocost plane with the indifference surface. Other
necessary assumptions are

Due to limited resources (finite income) an important constraint is also

index respectively. The assumption of “homothetic” preferences introduced later is valu-
able as a simplification in that it then does not matter to which period the utility level
refers (so that Laspeyres-KonUs and Paasche-KonUs coincide).

14One may make a distinction between consumption (creating utility) and consumption
expenditure. The difference is not only time but also household production as many
purchases are subject to a significant amount of processing (e.g. cooking) within the
households. Use of goods must also be distinguished from acquisition of goods. It is
assumed that goods are acquired by purchases and not received as payments in kind, gifts
or so.

15The familiar assumption her is that all income is spent for purchases. This rules
out that households take care of future consumption by saving. We then have a more
comfortable single period utility maximisation problem only.

16 [14]Diewert (2000) considered at length a model in which he relaxed the assumption
that “prices are constant across households” . The resulting equations (relating a disag-
gregated Laspeyres or Paasche index to the “usual” Laspeyres or Paasche index) are quite
complicated.

10



More intriguing information

1. American trade policy towards Sub Saharan Africa –- a meta analysis of AGOA
2. The name is absent
3. THE ECONOMICS OF COMPETITION IN HEALTH INSURANCE- THE IRISH CASE STUDY.
4. Bridging Micro- and Macro-Analyses of the EU Sugar Program: Methods and Insights
5. The name is absent
6. Evidence-Based Professional Development of Science Teachers in Two Countries
7. Telecommuting and environmental policy - lessons from the Ecommute program
8. Restructuring of industrial economies in countries in transition: Experience of Ukraine
9. Macro-regional evaluation of the Structural Funds using the HERMIN modelling framework
10. Trade and Empire, 1700-1870
11. A Consistent Nonparametric Test for Causality in Quantile
12. The name is absent
13. The fundamental determinants of financial integration in the European Union
14. Growth and Technological Leadership in US Industries: A Spatial Econometric Analysis at the State Level, 1963-1997
15. The name is absent
16. Proceedings of the Fourth International Workshop on Epigenetic Robotics
17. Improving Business Cycle Forecasts’ Accuracy - What Can We Learn from Past Errors?
18. SOCIOECONOMIC TRENDS CHANGING RURAL AMERICA
19. The name is absent
20. The name is absent