How do investors' expectations drive asset prices?



where by tr {■} we denote the trace of a 2 × 2-matrix and by (∙, ■) the inner
product of the Euclidean space R2. Hence, we have for 0
t T

0 = ut(t,x) ʌɑ(t, x) xtx2ux 1(t, x) — λ^2(t, x) σv(t,x) ux2(t,x')
+ j (-H-'d "ʃ (t,x) + (σv(t,x))2 ux2x2(t,x^ + b(t,x) ux(tt,x)
u(T,x) = xt
.

We jump directly to Step ⅛, omitting Step 3: We define Yt = u(t,Xt) and
Zt = στ (t, Xt,u(t, Xt)) у u(t,Xt), then (X,Y, Z) is an adapted solution of
(11) and (12).                                                                

Theorem 1 shows the close relationship between the asset price process
and the information process. Given the information process and the pricing
kernel Theorem 1 establishes a characterization of the asset price process
as a function of the information process and the pricing kernel. The drift
of the asset price process is governed by the market price of risk
λt and
the diffusion of the asset price process
Zt. The diffusion Zt depends on the
information process
It itself, on the volatility process of It, i.e. σ1t, and on
the first derivatives w.r.t.
xt and X2 of the function characterizing the asset
p
rice: ⅛ & i, σ1t ),    (t, It, σ1t ). Thus, with Theorem 1 we have an explicit

representation of the asset price process in terms of the information process
and the pricing kernel for a 2-dimensional market model. The application of
Theorem 1 to п-dimensional market models is straight forward.

It is obvious from Theorem 1 that the drift of the asset price process
depends on the volatility of the information process. Thus, empirical stud-
ies implicitly assuming non stochastic volatility of the information process
may find unexplainable variations in the drift. Further, neglecting stochastic
volatility of the information process leads to only one risk premium in the
asset price process, i.e.
σY = 0 provides Zt2 = = 0.

To gain some better understanding of the implications of Theorem 1 in
the remainder of this section we discuss the case when all the coefficients are
only functions in t. Thus, with this assumption equation (10) simplifies to

0 = ut(t,x1,x2) λ^1 ( (t) x1x2ux 1(t,x1,x2)                  (13)

λ^( (t) σy(t) ux2(t,x1,x2)

+ 2 ^xlx2 uχtχt(t,x1,x2 ) + v (t))2
u
a¾a¾
(t, xl, X-)^

+b(t) ux2(t,X1,X2) ,   0 tT,

u(T, x) = x1

16



More intriguing information

1. The name is absent
2. The name is absent
3. Cardiac Arrhythmia and Geomagnetic Activity
4. The name is absent
5. Human Development and Regional Disparities in Iran:A Policy Model
6. The name is absent
7. O funcionalismo de Sellars: uma pesquisa histδrica
8. Research Design, as Independent of Methods
9. Structural Breakpoints in Volatility in International Markets
10. Human Rights Violations by the Executive: Complicity of the Judiciary in Cameroon?
11. The Economics of Uncovered Interest Parity Condition for Emerging Markets: A Survey
12. The purpose of this paper is to report on the 2008 inaugural Equal Opportunities Conference held at the University of East Anglia, Norwich
13. Discourse Patterns in First Language Use at Hcme and Second Language Learning at School: an Ethnographic Approach
14. Valuing Access to our Public Lands: A Unique Public Good Pricing Experiment
15. The name is absent
16. The name is absent
17. The Economic Value of Basin Protection to Improve the Quality and Reliability of Potable Water Supply: Some Evidence from Ecuador
18. The name is absent
19. Investment and Interest Rate Policy in the Open Economy
20. A multistate demographic model for firms in the province of Gelderland