How do investors' expectations drive asset prices?



price process of the asset Ft must be equal at time T. Thus, by definition
Fτ = Iτ. Hence, by postulating such an information process It the value of
the asset in
T which is equal to the cash flow at date T is given. Equation
(1) is a generalization of the information process considered in Franke, Sta-
pleton, Subrahmanyam [12]. While their information process is modeled as
a geometric Brownian motion, equation
(1) admits constant, time varying,
deterministic or stochastic volatility.

In the remainder of this paper σ {Iu O иt} represents the filtration
generated by
It which by assumption represents all the information available
to investors in
t. We will now turn to the economic meaning of different
volatility models. First take the case of constant volatility, i.e. σ{
= σθ for
all
t [O, T]. Hence, the logarithm of It is normally distributed with ex-

pectation Ep (In Iτσ {Iu O и t}) = In (It)

(T t) and variance


var (In Itσ {Iu O и t}) = (σθ)2 (T t) for O t T. Since the price
of the asset in
T is equal to It this implies that the uncertainty about the
final value of the asset is a linearly decreasing function of time.

This constant rate of uncertainty resolution over time implies some special
information flow. The intensity of information arrival must be constant over
time, i.e. there are no periods where more information is getting into the
market than during other periods. Deterministic but time varying volatility
would allow for periods with a more intense information flow, but uncertainty
resolution is still a deterministic function of time. Such deterministic time
patterns might be explained by some sort of clustering of the information
flow; companies announcing their results in certain periods, e.g. at the end
of a year, many macroeconomic announcements such as monthly economic
information releases occur at certain week-days (see Ederington and Lee [7]
for a related econometric study). These facts may explain to some degree a
deterministic time pattern of the volatility of the information process. Hence,
under the assumption of time varying volatility the conditional variance of
It is no more linear in t. But the volatility and the process of conditional
variances of
It can still be perfectly forecasted.

Since the information process is governed by such scheduled information
releases but also by unforeseen information events we consider some ran-
domness in the volatility of the information process to get a more realistic
model for the conditional expectations. First assume that volatility is a borel



More intriguing information

1. The name is absent
2. The name is absent
3. Regional differentiation in the Russian federation: A cluster-based typification
4. The name is absent
5. References
6. Improvements in medical care and technology and reductions in traffic-related fatalities in Great Britain
7. A model-free approach to delta hedging
8. Target Acquisition in Multiscale Electronic Worlds
9. The Role of Trait Emotional Intelligence (El) in the Workplace.
10. The name is absent
11. The name is absent
12. Confusion and Reinforcement Learning in Experimental Public Goods Games
13. New issues in Indian macro policy.
14. DETERMINANTS OF FOOD AWAY FROM HOME AMONG AFRICAN-AMERICANS
15. Flatliners: Ideology and Rational Learning in the Diffusion of the Flat Tax
16. The name is absent
17. The name is absent
18. The Role of Land Retirement Programs for Management of Water Resources
19. Estimated Open Economy New Keynesian Phillips Curves for the G7
20. AN EMPIRICAL INVESTIGATION OF THE PRODUCTION EFFECTS OF ADOPTING GM SEED TECHNOLOGY: THE CASE OF FARMERS IN ARGENTINA