Prizes and Patents: Using Market Signals to Provide Incentives for Innovations



results extend readily to the case in which this cost is drawn from some distribution, say, G(K) and
is private information to the innovator. To see this extension, consider a mechanism in which the
innovator’s prize is given by the social surplus if the innovator’s and competitor’s reports agree, so
that
Ti(θ, θ) = S(θ) and the innovator receives no prize if the reports disagree so that Ti(θ, θc) = 0
if
θ = θc. Clearly, truth telling is incentive compatible and the mechanism implements the efficient
allocation in the sense that
δ(θ) = 1 if and only if S(θ)K.

B. Unique implementation of prize mechanisms

The mechanism that we have discussed uses information from the competitor to reward the
innovator. Under our particular mechanism, the competitor is indifferent about what information
to report. Truth telling is one of the equilibria of the game. Typically, the game has many other
equilibria. A natural question is whether we can design a mechanism which is ex post efficient
and has a unique equilibrium. Here, we adapt the mechanism of Moore and Repullo (1988) to our
environment. We show that such a mechanism has a unique subgame-perfect equilibrium in which
both the innovator and the competitor report the truth.

The mechanism has two stages. In Stage 1, the innovator and the competitor make reports
to the planner. Denote the report of the innovator by
θi and that of the competitor by θc. If
θi = θc, equals say θ, then implement the ex post efficient outcome associated with the common
report
θ. If θi = θc, then move to Stage 2. In Stage 2, the innovator is given a choice between
two alternatives, denoted by A and B. In each alternative, the innovator is granted a patent with
the length
μq (0i, θc) and μβ i, θc) and prizes Tq (0i, θc) and Tb (0i, θc) chosen to satisfy for all
ic)

max '.   (θic) π (θi) - K + Taic) ; Taic)}                    (9)

>  max {μβ (0i,0c) π (0J - K + Tb0c) ; Tbi, θc)} ,

max {μB i, θc) π (θc) - K + Tb (0i,0c) ; Tb (¾0c)}                 (10)

>  max {μq 0c) π (θi) - K + Tq 0c) ; Tq i,0c)} ,

T (θ,θ) - K> max {μB (θ, θ) π (θ) - K + Tb (θ, θ) ; Tb (θ, θ)} .              (11)

The basic idea behind this mechanism is that in the second stage, the innovator is given an

13



More intriguing information

1. Demand Potential for Goat Meat in Southern States: Empirical Evidence from a Multi-State Goat Meat Consumer Survey
2. Existentialism: a Philosophy of Hope or Despair?
3. Learning-by-Exporting? Firm-Level Evidence for UK Manufacturing and Services Sectors
4. ENERGY-RELATED INPUT DEMAND BY CROP PRODUCERS
5. Tourism in Rural Areas and Regional Development Planning
6. The name is absent
7. Skills, Partnerships and Tenancy in Sri Lankan Rice Farms
8. Ruptures in the probability scale. Calculation of ruptures’ values
9. The Impact of Optimal Tariffs and Taxes on Agglomeration
10. Iconic memory or icon?
11. Outsourcing, Complementary Innovations and Growth
12. Does Competition Increase Economic Efficiency in Swedish County Councils?
13. Emissions Trading, Electricity Industry Restructuring and Investment in Pollution Abatement
14. The economic value of food labels: A lab experiment on safer infant milk formula
15. A Principal Components Approach to Cross-Section Dependence in Panels
16. MULTIPLE COMPARISONS WITH THE BEST: BAYESIAN PRECISION MEASURES OF EFFICIENCY RANKINGS
17. THE WELFARE EFFECTS OF CONSUMING A CANCER PREVENTION DIET
18. The name is absent
19. Public-Private Partnerships in Urban Development in the United States
20. The name is absent