Non Linear Contracting and Endogenous Buyer Power between Manufacturers and Retailers: Empirical Evidence on Food Retailing in France



The previous equations stand for the pricing of brands owned by manufacturers who retail their
products through a downstream intermediary. Private labels (store brands) pricing obviously does
not follow the same pricing equilibrium. However the retailers’ profits coming from private labels
are implicitly taken into account in the incentive and participation constraints of retailers when
manufacturers make take-it-or-leave-it offers. Taking into account the possibility of endogenous
entry and exit of private label products by retailers is out of the scope of this paper.

Thus, in the case of private label products, retailers (who are also "manufacturers") choose
retail prices and bear the marginal cost of production and distribution, solving :

max V    (ps - μs - cs)ss{p) - V       (ps - ws - cs)ss(p)

{pi }-^0 δ—'sSr                            s—<sSr Sr

k^2 оj о t ɔr

where Sr is the set of private label products of retailer r. Thus, for private label products, additional
equations are obtained from the first order conditions of the profit maximization of retailers that
both produce and retail these products. The first order conditions give

Σ ⅛s - Ms - Cs) ds" (p>> + Sj (p) + ^  (ps - Ws - Cs) ds" (p>> = 0 for all jSr

*ppj                                             *ppj

sSr                                        sSr Sr

which can be written

(p - Ms - cs) dSs(p) + Sj (p) -  (ws - Ms) dSs(p) = 0 for aj Sr

s^             ∂pj           s^           ∂pj

<jΓ<√                          j -J                    ,-rv∖p5                    j -J

ssr                                           s Sr Sr

In matrix notation, these first order conditions are : for r = 1,..,R

(IrSpIr)(7 + r)+ IrS(p) - IrSpIrΓ = 0                        (13)

where Ir is the ownership matrix of private label products by retailer r.

We thus obtain a system of equations with (12) and (13) where 7 + Γ and Γ are unknown,
which is the following :

ʃʃfSp(7 + Γ) + If s(p)~- If Sp(I - If )Γ = 0 for f = 1,.., F
t (IrSpIr)(7 + Γ) + Irs(p) - IrSpIrΓ = 0 for r = 1,.., R

After solving the system (see appendix 7.1), we obtain the expression for the total price-cost margin
of all products as a function of demand parameters, of the structure of the industry and the vector

15



More intriguing information

1. Nietzsche, immortality, singularity and eternal recurrence1
2. Qualification-Mismatch and Long-Term Unemployment in a Growth-Matching Model
3. Secondary stress in Brazilian Portuguese: the interplay between production and perception studies
4. The magnitude and Cyclical Behavior of Financial Market Frictions
5. Personal Experience: A Most Vicious and Limited Circle!? On the Role of Entrepreneurial Experience for Firm Survival
6. Evolution of cognitive function via redeployment of brain areas
7. The name is absent
8. The name is absent
9. Correlation Analysis of Financial Contagion: What One Should Know Before Running a Test
10. The growing importance of risk in financial regulation
11. TINKERING WITH VALUATION ESTIMATES: IS THERE A FUTURE FOR WILLINGNESS TO ACCEPT MEASURES?
12. Migrant Business Networks and FDI
13. The name is absent
14. Growth and Technological Leadership in US Industries: A Spatial Econometric Analysis at the State Level, 1963-1997
15. Optimal Tax Policy when Firms are Internationally Mobile
16. Long-Term Capital Movements
17. The name is absent
18. Testing the Information Matrix Equality with Robust Estimators
19. The Determinants of Individual Trade Policy Preferences: International Survey Evidence
20. THE CHANGING RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN FEDERAL, STATE AND LOCAL GOVERNMENTS