Markets for Influence



4 Concluding comments

In this paper, we have shown that the standard Tullock contest game is strate-
gically isomorphic to a Cournot oligopoly game if effort in the Tullock contest
is mapped to outputs in the oligopoly game. Consideration of this isomorphism
indicates some differences in the aspects of the problem considered in the two
literatures. Analysis of Tullock contests has focused on differences in the success
function, while the oligopoly literature has paid more attention to the determi-
nation of the strategic variable. In each case, a range of possible outcomes from
complete rent dissipation to sharing of the maximum rent may be obtained in
appropriate cases.

Understanding of the relationship between contests and imperfectly compet-
itive markets is hampered by the absence of explicit prices and quantities in the
standard contest model. When contests are represented as markets for influ-
ence, we derive a natural strategic equivalence between the standard Tullock
contest and an oligopsonistic market in which expenditure is the strategic vari-
able. Unlike the corresponding case for oligopoly, this outcome turns out to be
less competitive (and hence less dissipative of rent) than the Cournot solution.

Representation of Tullock contests as markets for influence raises a wide
range of possible future developments. Most obviously, the literature on indus-
trial organization focuses on the extent to which the choice of strategic variable
determines whether market outcomes will yield competitive (Bertrand) out-
comes, less competitive (Cournot outcomes) or joint monopoly outcomes, not
to mention a wide range of intermediate possibilities. Analogies with Tullock
contests, including elections, litigation and so on may be fruitful. Beyond this,
it would be natural to consider the implications of the literature on mergers to
determine conditions under which participants in a Tullock contests, such as
political parties, might benefit from the formation of a coalition.

References

[1] Baye, M. R., and Hopee, H. C. (2003), ‘The strategic equivalence of rent-
seeking innovation, and patent-race games,’
Games and Economic Behavior
44, 217 -226.

[2] Baye, M. R., Kovenock, D., and de Vries, C. G. (1994), ‘The solution to
the Tullock rent-seeking game when R
2: Mixed-strategy equilibria and
dissipation rates,’
Public Choice 81, 362-380.

[3] Grant, S. and Quiggin, J. (1994), ‘Nash equilibrium with markup-pricing
oligopolists’,
Economics Letters 45, 245-51.

[4] Klemperer, P. and M. Meyer, 1989, ‘Supply function equilibria in oligopoly
under uncertainty,’
Econometrica 57, 1243-1277.



More intriguing information

1. Perceived Market Risks and Strategic Risk Management of Food Manufactures: Empirical Results from the German Brewing Industry
2. The name is absent
3. The name is absent
4. Surveying the welfare state: challenges, policy development and causes of resilience
5. Convergence in TFP among Italian Regions - Panel Unit Roots with Heterogeneity and Cross Sectional Dependence
6. THE CHANGING STRUCTURE OF AGRICULTURE
7. The name is absent
8. THE MEXICAN HOG INDUSTRY: MOVING BEYOND 2003
9. TINKERING WITH VALUATION ESTIMATES: IS THERE A FUTURE FOR WILLINGNESS TO ACCEPT MEASURES?
10. Social Irresponsibility in Management
11. The name is absent
12. The name is absent
13. Human Development and Regional Disparities in Iran:A Policy Model
14. The voluntary welfare associations in Germany: An overview
15. The name is absent
16. Are combination forecasts of S&P 500 volatility statistically superior?
17. The fundamental determinants of financial integration in the European Union
18. Workforce or Workfare?
19. Cross-Country Evidence on the Link between the Level of Infrastructure and Capital Inflows
20. Strengthening civil society from the outside? Donor driven consultation and participation processes in Poverty Reduction Strategies (PRSP): the Bolivian case