Markets for Influence



As before, we assume that the success probabilities are given by

e»

n

Σ½

J=1


(3)


n

eJ

j=i

where we assume, for simplicity, that R = 1 and the prize is normalized to one
so that
i’s payoff is given by πe». One can immediately see that such context
is essentially isomorphic to a oligopsony game as described below.

Proposition 2 A standard Tullock contest characterised by payoff function
—ff--e
», i = 1, ...,n, is strategically equivalent to a oligopsony game where:

∑≡j

J=l

(i) the strategic variable for firm i is the quantity purchased of an input
x» > 0;

(ii) output is given by the production function f (x») = X»;

(iii) the (constant) output priceis p = A — 1

(iv) A is sufficiently large that the input supply price w = A ^1is always
Σ ^i
i=l

positive.

Proof: Each firm i chooses X» to maximise profits, which can be written as:

к» = pf (x»)wx» = (A 1)x»


1

n

Σ X» .

»=1   /


X»


X»

X» ÷ m . (4)
Σ X»
»
=1


Then replace X» with e».

Proposition 2 above suggests that a Tullock contest will deliver outcomes
that are as competitive as those where the strategic variable is the quantity of
influenced purchased. This result is the oligopsony equivalent of Proposition 1.
This raises the following question: Would outcomes be more competitive if the
strategic variable were total expenditure?

The analogy with oligopoly can help us to answer this question. Grant
and Quiggin (1994) show that the equilibrium outcome with revenue as the
strategic variable is less competitive (higher price, lower aggregate quantity,
higher profit) than the Cournot-Nash equilibrium. This is because (loosely
speaking) if one player chooses to deviate by increasing revenue, this entails an
increase their own output and a reduction in the market price, and the Nash
assumption that other players will hold revenue constant implies that they must
increase quantity. Converse reasoning for the oligopsony case suggests that the
outcome of a standard Tullock contest with expenditure as a strategic variable
will be more competitive (lower price, higher aggregate quantity, more rent
dissipation) than the Cournot-Nash equilibrium. This is because an increase



More intriguing information

1. Apprenticeships in the UK: from the industrial-relation via market-led and social inclusion models
2. The name is absent
3. The Determinants of Individual Trade Policy Preferences: International Survey Evidence
4. The name is absent
5. Mergers under endogenous minimum quality standard: a note
6. The name is absent
7. Heavy Hero or Digital Dummy: multimodal player-avatar relations in FINAL FANTASY 7
8. The name is absent
9. Impacts of Tourism and Fiscal Expenditure on Remote Islands in Japan: A Panel Data Analysis
10. Target Acquisition in Multiscale Electronic Worlds
11. Behavior-Based Early Language Development on a Humanoid Robot
12. WP RR 17 - Industrial relations in the transport sector in the Netherlands
13. PRIORITIES IN THE CHANGING WORLD OF AGRICULTURE
14. The name is absent
15. THE WAEA -- WHICH NICHE IN THE PROFESSION?
16. What Drives the Productive Efficiency of a Firm?: The Importance of Industry, Location, R&D, and Size
17. Expectation Formation and Endogenous Fluctuations in Aggregate Demand
18. The name is absent
19. The voluntary welfare associations in Germany: An overview
20. Integration, Regional Specialization and Growth Differentials in EU Acceding Countries: Evidence from Hungary