Markets for Influence



in expenditure by one player raises the market price, and therefore lowers the

equilibrium quantity associated with a given expenditure level.

To verify this we first remind the reader that in the standard analysis of
Tullock games, player
i chooses eto maximise (1). The unique (symmetric)


Nash equilibrium is well-known and given by e*


To see this,
________ej________
(eι + (n-1)e)2
n

up to e*
i—1


note that n-21 is the solution to °^x I
n2                               oeγ 1


n1

= ■

e2 e3 —.


e* for i = 1,..., n.

_    1


ee   eι+(n-1)e


1 = 0. This implies that the total resources spent by players add


n1

*
n


Second, consider the Cournot-Nash strategic representation where the can-
didates choose quantity
θi to maximise:


Ki


i

P E3 θ


i.


It is easy to see that this representation has a unique symmetric equilibrium


where


θc _ θc _  _ θc

θ1 = θ2 = ... = θn


n 1

nʌ/n + 1 ’


and consequently


= n 1

n + 1


and


ec


(n - 1)
n(n + 1)


n

ΣC C
ei = ne

i—1


(n -1)

(n + 1).


(5)


This impliesless rent dissipation than the standard solution for the Tullock con-
test as
(n+1) < n-1 always holds.

Finally, we consider a strategic representation of markets for influence that is
equivalent to a ‘Bertrand’ model of oligopoly. Under this scenario the candidates
compete for voters in the ‘prices’ space. We impose the standard assumptions
in Bertrand competition, where the voters will vote for the candidate who offers
the higher price. In the event that both candidates offer the same price, voters
are equally split among the two candidates. It is not difficult to see that the
Bertrand (auction) logic implies that in equilibrium:

,,b =   =    = 1

p1 = ... = pn = 1.

That is, any price lower than one leads to ‘undercutting’. Under this equilib-
rium, there is zero profit, that is, full rent dissipation, as

θB _  _ θB

θ 1 — ... — θ 2


1= eB
n


... en .


(6)


The discussion suggests that by considering the full range of strategies avail-
able to participants in Tullock contests, it is possible to obtain a wide range of
symmetric equilibrium outcomes, just as in the case of oligopoly.



More intriguing information

1. Geography, Health, and Demo-Economic Development
2. The name is absent
3. Achieving the MDGs – A Note
4. The Functions of Postpartum Depression
5. BARRIERS TO EFFICIENCY AND THE PRIVATIZATION OF TOWNSHIP-VILLAGE ENTERPRISES
6. Environmental Regulation, Market Power and Price Discrimination in the Agricultural Chemical Industry
7. Program Semantics and Classical Logic
8. The name is absent
9. From Aurora Borealis to Carpathians. Searching the Road to Regional and Rural Development
10. The name is absent
11. On the origin of the cumulative semantic inhibition effect
12. The name is absent
13. The name is absent
14. STIMULATING COOPERATION AMONG FARMERS IN A POST-SOCIALIST ECONOMY: LESSONS FROM A PUBLIC-PRIVATE MARKETING PARTNERSHIP IN POLAND
15. The effect of classroom diversity on tolerance and participation in England, Sweden and Germany
16. The Impact of Financial Openness on Economic Integration: Evidence from the Europe and the Cis
17. The name is absent
18. From music student to professional: the process of transition
19. Demand Potential for Goat Meat in Southern States: Empirical Evidence from a Multi-State Goat Meat Consumer Survey
20. The name is absent