Estimating the Technology of Cognitive and Noncognitive Skill Formation



these features of the model does not prevent identification of the distribution of θ.

Nevertheless, various normalizations ensuring that the functions aj (θ, εj) are fully iden-
tified are available. For example, if each element of ε
j is normalized to be uniform (or any
other known distribution), the a
j (θ, εj) are fully identified. Other normalizations discussed
in Matzkin (2003, 2007) are also possible. Alternatively, one may assume that the a
j (θ, εj)
are separable in ε
j with zero conditional mean of εj given θ.21 We invoke these assumptions
when we identify the policy function for investments in Section 3.6.2 below.

The conditions justifying Theorems 1 and 2 are not nested within each other. Their dif-
ferent assumptions represent different trade-offs best suited for different applications. While
Theorem 1 would suffice for the empirical analysis of this paper, the general result established
in Theorem 2 will likely be quite useful as larger sample sizes become available.

Carneiro, Hansen, and Heckman (2003) present an analysis for nonseparable measurement
equations based on a separable latent index structure, but invoke strong independence and
“identification-at-infinity” assumptions. Our approach for identifying the distribution of θ
from general nonseparable measurement equations does not require these strong assumptions.
Note that it also allows the θ to determine all measurements and for the θ to be freely
correlated.

3.4 Nonparametric Identification of the Technology Function

Suppose that the shocks ηk,t are independent over time. Below, we analyze a more general
case that allows for serial dependence. Once the density of θ is known, one can identify
nonseparable technology function (2.1) for t
{1, . . . , T}; k {C, N}; and s {1, ...., S}.

Even if (θt, It, θP) were perfectly observed, one could not separately identify the distribution
of η
k,t and the function fk,s because, without further normalizations, a change in the density
of η
k,t can be undone by a change in the function fk,s.22

One solution to this problem is to assume that (2.1) is additively separable in ηk,t. An-
other way to avoid this ambiguity is to normalize η
k,t to have a uniform density on [0, 1].
Any of the normalizations suggested by Matzkin (2003, 2007) could be used. Assuming η
k,t
is uniform [0, 1] , we establish that fk,s is nonparametrically identified, by noting that, from
the knowledge of p
θ we can calculate, for any θ R,

Pr [θk,t+ι θθt, Ik,t, θp] ≡ G (⅜, Ik,t, θp) .

21Observe that Theorem 2 covers the identifiability of the outcome (Qj) functions (2.2) even if we supple-
ment the model with errors ε
j , j {1, . . . , J} that satisfy the conditions of the theorem.

22See, e.g, Matzkin (2003, 2007).

15



More intriguing information

1. sycnoιogιcaι spaces
2. Short Term Memory May Be the Depletion of the Readily Releasable Pool of Presynaptic Neurotransmitter Vesicles
3. The name is absent
4. Equity Markets and Economic Development: What Do We Know
5. Does Competition Increase Economic Efficiency in Swedish County Councils?
6. The name is absent
7. The name is absent
8. The name is absent
9. The magnitude and Cyclical Behavior of Financial Market Frictions
10. The name is absent