these features of the model does not prevent identification of the distribution of θ.
Nevertheless, various normalizations ensuring that the functions aj (θ, εj) are fully iden-
tified are available. For example, if each element of εj is normalized to be uniform (or any
other known distribution), the aj (θ, εj) are fully identified. Other normalizations discussed
in Matzkin (2003, 2007) are also possible. Alternatively, one may assume that the aj (θ, εj)
are separable in εj with zero conditional mean of εj given θ.21 We invoke these assumptions
when we identify the policy function for investments in Section 3.6.2 below.
The conditions justifying Theorems 1 and 2 are not nested within each other. Their dif-
ferent assumptions represent different trade-offs best suited for different applications. While
Theorem 1 would suffice for the empirical analysis of this paper, the general result established
in Theorem 2 will likely be quite useful as larger sample sizes become available.
Carneiro, Hansen, and Heckman (2003) present an analysis for nonseparable measurement
equations based on a separable latent index structure, but invoke strong independence and
“identification-at-infinity” assumptions. Our approach for identifying the distribution of θ
from general nonseparable measurement equations does not require these strong assumptions.
Note that it also allows the θ to determine all measurements and for the θ to be freely
correlated.
3.4 Nonparametric Identification of the Technology Function
Suppose that the shocks ηk,t are independent over time. Below, we analyze a more general
case that allows for serial dependence. Once the density of θ is known, one can identify
nonseparable technology function (2.1) for t ∈ {1, . . . , T}; k ∈ {C, N}; and s ∈ {1, ...., S}.
Even if (θt, It, θP) were perfectly observed, one could not separately identify the distribution
of ηk,t and the function fk,s because, without further normalizations, a change in the density
of ηk,t can be undone by a change in the function fk,s.22
One solution to this problem is to assume that (2.1) is additively separable in ηk,t. An-
other way to avoid this ambiguity is to normalize ηk,t to have a uniform density on [0, 1].
Any of the normalizations suggested by Matzkin (2003, 2007) could be used. Assuming ηk,t
is uniform [0, 1] , we establish that fk,s is nonparametrically identified, by noting that, from
the knowledge of pθ we can calculate, for any θ ∈ R,
Pr [θk,t+ι ≤ θ∣θt, Ik,t, θp] ≡ G (⅜, Ik,t, θp) .
21Observe that Theorem 2 covers the identifiability of the outcome (Qj) functions (2.2) even if we supple-
ment the model with errors εj , j ∈ {1, . . . , J} that satisfy the conditions of the theorem.
22See, e.g, Matzkin (2003, 2007).
15
More intriguing information
1. BARRIERS TO EFFICIENCY AND THE PRIVATIZATION OF TOWNSHIP-VILLAGE ENTERPRISES2. Cancer-related electronic support groups as navigation-aids: Overcoming geographic barriers
3. Endogenous Determination of FDI Growth and Economic Growth:The OECD Case
4. The Integration Order of Vector Autoregressive Processes
5. Magnetic Resonance Imaging in patients with ICDs and Pacemakers
6. Impacts of Tourism and Fiscal Expenditure on Remote Islands in Japan: A Panel Data Analysis
7. Towards Learning Affective Body Gesture
8. The name is absent
9. Workforce or Workfare?
10. Permanent and Transitory Policy Shocks in an Empirical Macro Model with Asymmetric Information