The name is absent



significant control. In addition, the results show the importance of the initial invasion size in determining
the optimal policy. Propositions 1 or 2 may apply when the invasion is small while Proposition 7 may
simultaneously apply when the invasion is large. In such cases the optimal policy is path dependent and
there is an economic rationale for eradication if the invasion is small, but not if the invasion is large.

The paper also illustrates the information that is needed to evaluate the economic efficiency of
invasive species control. Estimates of the costs of control, damages from an invasion, and the invasion
growth rate are required. These may be difficult to assess, particularly in the early stages of an invasion.
Yet this is precisely the time when prompt action can reduce future consequences.

There are a number of important issues related to invasive species problems that are not
addressed in this paper. There are many circumstances where prevention may be the best control.
Similarly, our model does not consider the possibility of re-invasion. Clearly, the value of eradicating an
invasive species will depend on the likelihood that a new invasion might occur. Finally, many invasive
species problems involve private actions where individuals do not consider the consequences for social
welfare. The design of policies that mitigate the conflicts between private incentives and social welfare
is another interesting aspect of invasive species problems.

Appendix.

Proof of Lemma 1. The cost functions C and D are bounded continuous functions on their relevant
domains. Define the operator ΓV(y) = inf C(a,y) + D(x) + δV(f(x)) subject to y = x + a. By the
contraction mapping theorem maps the set of bounded continuous functions into itself. Hence, V is
continuous. We now show that V maps non-decreasing functions into non-decreasing functions.
Suppose V is non-decreasing. Let x and x' be optimal from y and y', respectively where y < y'. Suppose
x' < y. Then x' is feasible from y and ΓV(y) = C(y-x,y) + D(x) + δV(f(x))
C(y-x',y) + D(x') + δV(f(x'))
C(y'-x',y') + D(x') + δV(f(x')) = ΓV(y'), where the first inequality is due to optimality while the second

21



More intriguing information

1. Nach der Einführung von Arbeitslosengeld II: deutlich mehr Verlierer als Gewinner unter den Hilfeempfängern
2. Großhandel: Steigende Umsätze und schwungvolle Investitionsdynamik
3. The name is absent
4. Portuguese Women in Science and Technology (S&T): Some Gender Features Behind MSc. and PhD. Achievement
5. The Triangular Relationship between the Commission, NRAs and National Courts Revisited
6. A Note on Costly Sequential Search and Oligopoly Pricing (new title: Truly Costly Sequential Search and Oligopolistic Pricing,)
7. The name is absent
8. Has Competition in the Japanese Banking Sector Improved?
9. Ex post analysis of the regional impacts of major infrastructure: the Channel Tunnel 10 years on.
10. THE INTERNATIONAL OUTLOOK FOR U.S. TOBACCO
11. Inhimillinen pääoma ja palkat Suomessa: Paluu perusmalliin
12. Quality practices, priorities and performance: an international study
13. The Values and Character Dispositions of 14-16 Year Olds in the Hodge Hill Constituency
14. Migration and Technological Change in Rural Households: Complements or Substitutes?
15. The name is absent
16. CURRENT CHALLENGES FOR AGRICULTURAL POLICY
17. ISSUES AND PROBLEMS OF IMMEDIATE CONCERN
18. Conditions for learning: partnerships for engaging secondary pupils with contemporary art.
19. Announcement effects of convertible bond loans versus warrant-bond loans: An empirical analysis for the Dutch market
20. ISSUES IN NONMARKET VALUATION AND POLICY APPLICATION: A RETROSPECTIVE GLANCE