Notes on an Endogenous Growth Model with two Capital Stocks II: The Stochastic Case



The value of un (π, x0 , z0) is the sum of expected discounted returns in periods 0 through
n from plan π if the initial state is (x
0 , z0). Assumption 2 also ensures that for each
(x
o, z0) S we can define u(, x0, z0) : Π(xo, z0) RR to be the limit of the series as the
horizon recedes:

u(π, x0, z0) = lim un (π, x0, z0).
n→∞

Thus u(π, x0 , z0) is the infinite sum of expected discounted returns from the plan π if
the initial state is (x
0, z0). Under Assumptions 1 and 2, the function u(,x, z) is well
defined on the nonempty set Π(x, z), for each (x, z)
S. In this case we can define the
supremum function v
* : S R by:

v*(x,z) = sup u(π,x,z).
πΠ(x,z)

That is v* is the unique function satisfying the following two conditions:

v* u(π, x, z), all π Π(x, z);

v* = lim u(πk,x, z), for some sequence {πk} inΠ(x, z).
k→∞

In the bounded returns case, a solution v to the functional equation must have the
property that the expected discounted value of the implied policy in the very far future
is equal to zero, that is we exclude for example sustained overinvestment. The difficulty
with the unbounded returns case is that there may be some (x
0, z0) S and π Π(x0, z0)
for which the condition:

lim βt

t→∞


V v[∏t-i(zt-1 ),ztt(zo

Zt


, dzt) = 0,


π Π(x0, z0), (x0, z0) S


(37)


does not hold. For each (x0, z0) S, however, we can define Π(xo, z0) to be the subset
of Π(x
o, z0) on which this condition holds. Then define v : S R by

v(x, z) = sup u(π, x, z)

πΠ(x,z)

Clearly v v*. The following theorem provides sufficient conditions for the two functions
to be equal.

Theorem 3. Let (X, X ), (Z, Z), Q, Γ, F , and β satisfy Assumptions 1 and 2. Let Π,
Π, u, v*, and v be as defined above. Suppose v is a measurable function satisfying the
functional equation

[f(x,y,z)+ β J v(y,z')Q(z,dz')j,


v(x, z) = sup

yΓ(x,z)

and that the associated policy correspondence G is nonempty and permits a measurable
selection. For each
(x, z) S, let π*(,x, z) be a plan generated by G from (x, z). Suppose
in addition that

(a) π*(,x, z) Π(x, z);and

(b) for any (xo, zo) S and π Π(xo, zo), there exists π IΠ(x, z) such that u(π, x, z)
u(π, x, z).

Then v*(x, z) = v(x, z) = v(x, z) = u(π*(;x, z), x, z), (x, z) S.

Proof. See Stokey and Lucas (1989), page 274.                                     □

In the next sections we will apply this theorem to our model.

15



More intriguing information

1. The name is absent
2. Should Local Public Employment Services be Merged with the Local Social Benefit Administrations?
3. CAPACITAÇÃO GERENCIAL DE AGRICULTORES FAMILIARES: UMA PROPOSTA METODOLÓGICA DE EXTENSÃO RURAL
4. ASSESSMENT OF MARKET RISK IN HOG PRODUCTION USING VALUE-AT-RISK AND EXTREME VALUE THEORY
5. A Critical Examination of the Beliefs about Learning a Foreign Language at Primary School
6. The name is absent
7. Foreign Direct Investment and Unequal Regional Economic Growth in China
8. The name is absent
9. The name is absent
10. Temporary Work in Turbulent Times: The Swedish Experience
11. The name is absent
12. The name is absent
13. THE DIGITAL DIVIDE: COMPUTER USE, BASIC SKILLS AND EMPLOYMENT
14. Database Search Strategies for Proteomic Data Sets Generated by Electron Capture Dissociation Mass Spectrometry
15. Cyclical Changes in Short-Run Earnings Mobility in Canada, 1982-1996
16. The name is absent
17. The name is absent
18. Evolution of cognitive function via redeployment of brain areas
19. Perceived Market Risks and Strategic Risk Management of Food Manufactures: Empirical Results from the German Brewing Industry
20. EFFICIENCY LOSS AND TRADABLE PERMITS