time τ passes between the end of the first bargaining stage (an acceptance) and the
beginning of a new bargaining stage (a new proposal). Moreover, the first proposer
at the second stage is the last responder at the initial stage. Player i’s rate of time
preference is indicated by ri > 0 (and i =1, 2). To take into account that there are
intervals of time of different lengths, we define players discount factors as follows:
player i’s within-cake discount factor δi =exp(-ri∆) applies after a rejection and his
between-cake discount factor αi =exp(-riτ) applies after an acceptance. Moreover,
players are allowed to have different valuations of the issues. A positive parameter
λi indicates the relative importance of cake i to player i (see payoff functions below),
with i =1, 2.
The implementation of the agreement is assumed to be sequential, that is, a
division is implemented as soon as it is agreed. If an agreement is not reached on the
partition of a cake, players get zero payoffs (disagreement) at that stage. Then, if
disagreement takes place at the first stage, the second stage cannot take place and
players’ overall payoffs are zero. In our framework, we consider two agendas, agenda
i states that cake i is negotiated first, with i =1, 2. In this section we focus on
agenda 1. If, after t rounds, an agreement is reached on the division of the first cake,
(x, 1 - x), where x is the share player 1 obtains, and after n +1 periods (a period of
length τ and n periods of length ∆) another agreement is reached (1 - y, y), then the
More intriguing information
1. The name is absent2. The name is absent
3. The name is absent
4. Does Competition Increase Economic Efficiency in Swedish County Councils?
5. Draft of paper published in:
6. The name is absent
7. Methods for the thematic synthesis of qualitative research in systematic reviews
8. The Impact of Optimal Tariffs and Taxes on Agglomeration
9. The Composition of Government Spending and the Real Exchange Rate
10. The name is absent