Heterogeneity of Investors and Asset Pricing in a Risk-Value World



aggregate payoff ε. This result can be restated using the coefficient of the
negative third to the second derivative of the
F-function, —f-z(ei)/ʌ'(e). This
coefficient is called the coefficient of absolute prudence of the investor’s risk
function; it is the analogue to Kimball’s coefficient of absolute prudence. Mul-
tiplying equation (28) by
1, taking logs and differentiating with respect to
βj yields

d ln(dei∕de3) _ _ f ({e) ɪ f z(<¾) dei

(29)


dej           —f,j(ej)    —f'(ei) de

This proves the equivalence of the first two statements in Proposition
3. Substituting
dei∕dej in equation (29) from equation (28) shows that
d ln(dei∕de3∙)∕dβj > [_] [<] 0 if and only if (18) holds.                      

Appendix D: Proof of Proposition 4

For any HARA function,

f z(¾)

Ш (¾)]2


/f (ei).


Hence, by the last statement of Proposition 3, ei (ej■) is strictly convex
[linear] [strictly concave] if and only if

fi (ei)


di


< [_]    .        :

½∙


ej.


Hence, by equation (17), ei(ej■) is strictly convex [linear] [strictly concave]
if and only if investor i’s sharing constant is smaller than [equal to] [greater
than] that of investor j. This proves Proposition 4.                       

39



More intriguing information

1. Foreign direct investment in the Indian telecommunications sector
2. The Effects of Attendance on Academic Performance: Panel Data Evidence for Introductory Microeconomics
3. Unilateral Actions the Case of International Environmental Problems
4. Are combination forecasts of S&P 500 volatility statistically superior?
5. Educational Inequalities Among School Leavers in Ireland 1979-1994
6. The name is absent
7. Feature type effects in semantic memory: An event related potentials study
8. The name is absent
9. Exchange Rate Uncertainty and Trade Growth - A Comparison of Linear and Nonlinear (Forecasting) Models
10. Wirtschaftslage und Reformprozesse in Estland, Lettland, und Litauen: Bericht 2001