For marriage problems we even have a stronger result. Let μ 1,..., μk be k (possibly non-
distinct) stable matchings for a marriage problem and assume that each agent ranks these
matchings according to his/her preferences. Using linear programming tools, Teo and Sethu-
raman (1998, Theorem 2) showed that the map that assigns to each man his l-th (weakly)
best match and to each woman her (k - l + 1)-st (weakly) best match determines a well-
defined and stable matching. We explain and discuss (generalized) medians as compromise
solutions for two-sided matching problems in Klaus and Klijn (2006). Below we provide an
elementary proof of this “generalized median result” for marriage problems.
Consider a marriage problem (M∪W, (°i)i∈N). Let μ 1,..., μk be k (possibly non-distinct)
stable matchings. Let each agent rank these matchings according to his/her preferences as
explained before. Formally, for each i ∈ M ∪ W there is a sequence of matchings (μi1,..., μzk)
such that {μi1,..., μzk} = {μ 1,..., μk} and for any l ∈ {1,... ,k — 1}, μli ( i ) °i μ*i+1( i ). Thus,
for any l ∈ {1,...,k}, at μ*i agent i is assigned to his/her l-th (weakly) best match (among
the k stable matchings).
For any l ∈ {1, . . . , k}, we define the generalized median stable matching αl as the
function αl : M ∪ W → M ∪ W defined by
αi(i) :=
μli(i) if i ∈ M;
μi(k-l+1) (i) ifi∈W.
Theorem 3 Marriage and compromise (generalized medians)
Let μ1 , . . . , μk be k (possibly non-distinct) stable matchings for a marriage problem. Then,
for any l ∈ {1, . . . , k}, αl is a well-defined stable matching.
Proof Let l ∈ {1, . . . , k}. First, we show that αl is a well-defined matching, i.e., αl is of
order 2. Let m ∈ M with αl (m) = w ∈ W. We have to prove that αl (αl (m)) = m. Without
loss of generality, μ 1(m) °m μ2(m) °m ∙∙∙°m μι(m) °m ∙∙∙°m μk- 1(m) °m μk(m) and
αl(m) = μl(m). Then, μl(m) = αl(m) = w and μl(w) = m. By arguments similar to those
in the first part of the proof of Theorem 2,6
μ 1 °m ∙∙∙ °m μi- 1 °m μi °m μi+1 °m " ∙ °m μk
{μk, . . . , μl+1 } °w μl °w {μl- 1 , . . . , μ 1 }
In particular, μi(w) is the (k — l + 1)-st ranked match for woman w and therefore αi (w) =
μi(w). Hence, αi(αi(m)) = αi(w) = μi(w) = m.
We now prove that αi is stable. By definition, αi is individually rational. Suppose there
is a blocking pair {m, w} with m ∈ M and w ∈ W, i.e., w Âm αi(m) and m Âw αi(w). Then,
m prefers w to at least k— l + 1 stable matchings in {μ1, . . . , μk}. Similarly, w prefers m to at
least l stable matchings in {μ1 , . . . , μk}. Hence, for at least one matching μ ∈ {μ1, . . . , μk},
w Âm μ(m) and m Âw μ(w), contradicting stability. ¥
6Recall that in the first part of the proof of Theorem 2 only the relative rankings of agent i’s mates with
respect to μk +1 mattered - which exact rank μk+1 had did not play any role in that part of the proof.
More intriguing information
1. The name is absent2. The name is absent
3. Two-Part Tax Controls for Forest Density and Rotation Time
4. Multiple Arrhythmogenic Substrate for Tachycardia in a
5. The name is absent
6. Nietzsche, immortality, singularity and eternal recurrence1
7. Survey of Literature on Covered and Uncovered Interest Parities
8. THE CHANGING RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN FEDERAL, STATE AND LOCAL GOVERNMENTS
9. Effects of a Sport Education Intervention on Students’ Motivational Responses in Physical Education
10. A Regional Core, Adjacent, Periphery Model for National Economic Geography Analysis