they are, shy away from risky projects and discount for statistical variance of the ERR when ranking
R&D projects. Therefore, the risk-averse version of the ranked distribution of R&D projects can be
thought of as positioned lower on the ERR scale than the risk-neutral version. This creates a
divergence between the ex ante and ex post rate-of-return distributions, as the latter will more or less
coincide with the risk-neutral version.
Arrow and Lindner (1970, 1972) argue that in a typical public-investment situation,
governments can safely ignore risk as long as the investment is small relative to national income.
Given that this is true for most public agricultural R&D investments, risk aversion should not play
much of a role in the selection of public agricultural R&D projects or programs (Anderson 1991). In
other words, public agricultural R&D projects or programs with the same ERR, but with one being
riskier than the other (reflected by a higher statistical variance), should be treated the same. The
chance of a lower outcome is compensated by the chance of a higher outcome. Despite this theoretical
argument, public-research administrators most likely act moderately risk-averse, so that demands for
short-term accountability can be answered by at least some positive results (Greig 1981).
Risk and uncertainty are not static and may decline over time. R&D proposals that are
initially turned down as being too risky may be selected at a later stage when critical variables can be
predicted more accurately. For example, experience in a certain research field may increase the
confidence in research effectiveness over time.
The six underlying factors presented here are not necessarily exhaustive. Other factors may
play a role as well. Moreover, the relative importance of each of the six factors differs across research
fields. Market structure, for example, does not play much of a role when considering public
(agricultural) R&D. For other fields of research, however, this may constitute a highly relevant factor
that affects the ERR of R&D projects and hence shape up the available R&D opportunities.
Understanding which factors are the most critical is important when considering policies that could
shift the portfolio of possible R&D projects higher up on the ERR scale.
Table 1 summarizes some of the government policies that could affect each of the six factors
positively. Several of these policies are far broader than just R&D policy. These policies condition the
extent to which R&D can contribute to the overall economy. In developing countries in particular, the
10
More intriguing information
1. Understanding the (relative) fall and rise of construction wages2. Palvelujen vienti ja kansainvälistyminen
3. ENVIRONMENTAL POLICY: THE LEGISLATIVE AND REGULATORY AGENDA
4. Evaluating the Success of the School Commodity Food Program
5. Aktive Klienten - Aktive Politik? (Wie) Läßt sich dauerhafte Unabhängigkeit von Sozialhilfe erreichen? Ein Literaturbericht
6. Clinical Teaching and OSCE in Pediatrics
7. Distortions in a multi-level co-financing system: the case of the agri-environmental programme of Saxony-Anhalt
8. Lumpy Investment, Sectoral Propagation, and Business Cycles
9. Elicited bid functions in (a)symmetric first-price auctions
10. Temporary Work in Turbulent Times: The Swedish Experience