far larger portfolio of profitable agricultural R&D investment opportunities than the developing
countries have. Their optimal R&D intensity (i.e., public agricultural research expenditures as a
percentage of AgGDP) stands at 2.8%, compared to 1.0% for developing countries (figure 5b).
A differentiation of the R&D opportunity curve for developing countries by regions is
presented in figure 5c. Although the actual R&D intensity for all three regions clusters around 0.5%,
their estimated optimal R&D intensity ratios differ quite significantly: 0.9% for Africa; 0.6% for Asia;
and 2.0% for Latin America. The robustness of these latter estimates is rather weak given the small
number of rate-of-return observations per region. Nevertheless, it illustrates how, with sufficiently
good rate-of-return data, some far-reaching conclusions regarding underinvestment in agricultural
R&D could be derived.
In figure 5d, the R&D opportunity curves have been plotted for two different time periods.
The results of the rate-of-return studies published in and before 1985 have been related to the
expenditure level of 1961-65, while those published after 1985 are related to the expenditure level of
1981-85. The figure shows how, for both developed and developing countries, the R&D opportunity
curve has shifted outward. If the R&D opportunity curve had not changed, the increase in R&D
spending would have reduced the implicit cut-off rate and, hence, the underinvestment gap. For
developing countries, this would have brought the cut-off rate close to 25%, while for developed
countries the cut-off rate would have dropped below zero.
An implicit assumption frequently made in the literature as well as in policy advice is that the
R&D opportunity curve is the same across countries and over time. For example, the recommendation
made by the World Bank that developing countries should invest 2% of their AgGDP in agricultural
R&D by 1990 (World Bank 1981) is based on this assumption. The developed-country investment
level of the early 1980s is taken as the target, and assuming that all countries are on the same curve,
closing the underinvestment gap is a matter of moving along a fixed curve. If the advice had been
followed, developing countries would have overinvested in agricultural R&D by quite a margin. The
results of the current analysis suggests that for 1981-85 the optimal investment level for developing
countries was about 1.0% (rather than the actual 0.4%) and that for developed countries, it was about
2.8% (rather than the actual 2.0%). It is important to realize that even at modest investment levels,
19
More intriguing information
1. The duration of fixed exchange rate regimes2. The name is absent
3. The name is absent
4. Evaluating Consumer Usage of Nutritional Labeling: The Influence of Socio-Economic Characteristics
5. The name is absent
6. Regulation of the Electricity Industry in Bolivia: Its Impact on Access to the Poor, Prices and Quality
7. The name is absent
8. DETERMINANTS OF FOOD AWAY FROM HOME AMONG AFRICAN-AMERICANS
9. The name is absent
10. The name is absent