The name is absent



We could estimate the parameters 0. = {β1t, β2t, β3t, λt} by nonlinear least squares, for each month t.
Following standard practice tracing to Nelson and Siegel (1987), however, we instead fix λt at a
prespecified value, which lets us compute the values of the two regressors (factor loadings) and use
ordinary least squares to estimate the betas (factors), for each month
t. Doing so enhances not only
simplicity and convenience, but also numerical trustworthiness, by enabling us to replace hundreds of
potentially challenging numerical optimizations with trivial least-squares regressions. The question
arises, of course, as to an appropriate value for λ
t. Recall that λt determines the maturity at which the
loading on the medium-term, or curvature, factor achieves it maximum. Two- or three-year maturities are
commonly used in that regard, so we simply picked the average, 30 months. The λ
t value that
maximizes the loading on the medium-term factor at exactly 30 months is λ
t=0.0609.

Applying ordinary least squares to the yield data for each month gives us a time series of
estimates of {fi1
1, β21, β31} and a corresponding panel of residuals, or pricing errors. Note that, because
the maturities are not equally spaced, we implicitly weight the most “active” region of the yield curve
most heavily when fitting the model.9 There are many aspects to a full assessment of the “fit” of our
model. In Figure 4 we plot the implied average fitted yield curve against the average actual yield curve.
The two agree quite closely. In Figure 5 we dig deeper by plotting the raw yield curve and the three-
factor fitted yield curve for some selected dates. Clearly the three-factor model is capable of replicating
a variety of yield curve shapes: upward sloping, downward sloping, humped, and inverted humped. It
does, however, have difficulties at some dates, especially when yields are dispersed, with multiple
interior minima and maxima. Overall, however, the residual plot in Figure 6 indicates a good fit.

In Table 2 we present statistics that describe the in-sample fit. The residual sample
autocorrelations indicate that pricing errors are persistent. As noted in Bliss (1997b), regardless of the
term structure estimation method used, there is a persistent discrepancy between actual bond prices and
prices estimated from term structure models. Presumably these discrepancies arise from persistent tax
and/or liquidity effects.10 However, because they persist, they should vanish from fitted yield changes.

In Figure 7 we plot {β1121 ,331} along with the empirical level, slope and curvature defined
earlier. The figure confirms our assertion that the three factors in our model correspond to level, slope

9 Other weightings and loss functions have been explored by Bliss (1997b), Soderlind and
Svensson (1997), and Bates (1999).

10 Although, as discussed earlier, we attempted to remove illiquid bonds, complete elimination is
not possible.



More intriguing information

1. Partner Selection Criteria in Strategic Alliances When to Ally with Weak Partners
2. The name is absent
3. The Interest Rate-Exchange Rate Link in the Mexican Float
4. Tastes, castes, and culture: The influence of society on preferences
5. The name is absent
6. Why unwinding preferences is not the same as liberalisation: the case of sugar
7. The name is absent
8. The name is absent
9. Clinical Teaching and OSCE in Pediatrics
10. Keystone sector methodology:network analysis comparative study
11. The name is absent
12. The name is absent
13. The name is absent
14. Do imputed education histories provide satisfactory results in fertility analysis in the Western German context?
15. The Impact of Minimum Wages on Wage Inequality and Employment in the Formal and Informal Sector in Costa Rica
16. Wettbewerbs- und Industriepolitik - EU-Integration als Dritter Weg?
17. Natural Resources: Curse or Blessing?
18. Gender and aquaculture: sharing the benefits equitably
19. The name is absent
20. The name is absent