Var If(xx )w [ nx ] dx
= ∫jf(X fy )C0V(W [ nχ ], W [ „y ]) dxdy
(A.19)
→fjʃ(Xfy)I(x=y)dxdy Var(w0) = 0.
Furthermore, denoting
S w(1) S w(x)
s„(F) F F(1) „ - ʃfx) „.lx,
and using the easy equality
∑E(w,wnT) = ∑' (w0'w) - £E(w0wτ),
t= 1 t= 1 j=0
(A.20)
(A.21)
Assumption 1 implies that sn(F) and wn are jointly normally distributed with covariance
n-[ nx ]-1
∑ e(w 0wT)
Covars„(F) , w„) = ʃf(x) — —-----dx O О(1/√n ).
„П
(A.22)
Finally, (A.2) implies that
s„(F) ⇒ D(1)(F(1) W(1) - ʃf(x) W(x)dx),
whereas
(A.23)
wn ~ Nq(0,DDtT) (A.24)
cf. (4). Lemma 2 now easily follows from these results. Q.E.D.
Proof of Lemma 3 : Let z = exp(2 ikπ/n ) = cos(2 kπ/n ) + i .sin(2 kπ/n ), and observe that zn = 1. Then
41
More intriguing information
1. The name is absent2. The name is absent
3. The name is absent
4. Social Balance Theory
5. The effect of classroom diversity on tolerance and participation in England, Sweden and Germany
6. The name is absent
7. Estimated Open Economy New Keynesian Phillips Curves for the G7
8. Group cooperation, inclusion and disaffected pupils: some responses to informal learning in the music classroom
9. Effects of red light and loud noise on the rate at which monkeys sample the sensory environment
10. DISCUSSION: ASSESSING STRUCTURAL CHANGE IN THE DEMAND FOR FOOD COMMODITIES