Intertemporal Risk Management Decisions of Farmers under Preference, Market, and Policy Dynamics



but only the turning points for the first two years (β= 0.3 and 0.5, respectively) are observable
within the range of
β. Third, for the last year when farming is about to end, the hedge ratio is
always around 25.5% for all
βlevels, quite different from the other years, especially those for the
second to fourth year.

Sinceβis defined as the time discount factor, by postponing consumption to next period
the farmer only gets a fraction (
β) of the utility that he or she would get by consuming an equal
amount during the current period. Therefore with a higher
β, the farmer will have a greater
propensity to consume in the future instead of the current time period. In our case, as
βbecomes
bigger or the future consumption is less discounted, the farmer values the future income and
income risk more than today’s, and hedging decreases in the early years. The hedge ratios are
increasing during the third until fifth year over all
βvalues, and increasing for the first two years
before
βgets to the turning point.

At a specific time preference level, the farmer tends to hedge more in earlier years due
to a preference for an early resolution of consumption risk. This pattern is more obvious in hedge
ratios when
βis low, but it then slowly changes as hedge ratios move to the turning point.
Intertemporal Substitutability

Optimal hedge ratios are generally sensitive to changes in intertemporal substitutability
as shown in figure 7. Hedging percentages are primarily increasing as
ρ gets larger. The pattern
switches when
ρreaches the turning point in the first and second year.

A larger ρrepresents a more substitution of consumption across years. Therefore,
optimal hedge ratios differ for large versus small
ρ values across the first four years, most
noticeably in the third and fourth year. For a range between -5 to 0.8, the increase in
ρfor a

22



More intriguing information

1. What Lessons for Economic Development Can We Draw from the Champagne Fairs?
2. Valuing Access to our Public Lands: A Unique Public Good Pricing Experiment
3. A Multimodal Framework for Computer Mediated Learning: The Reshaping of Curriculum Knowledge and Learning
4. Thresholds for Employment and Unemployment - a Spatial Analysis of German Regional Labour Markets 1992-2000
5. Une Gestion des ressources humaines à l'interface des organisations : vers une GRH territoriale ?
6. Co-ordinating European sectoral policies against the background of European Spatial Development
7. The name is absent
8. Climate change, mitigation and adaptation: the case of the Murray–Darling Basin in Australia
9. The name is absent
10. Are class size differences related to pupils’ educational progress and classroom processes? Findings from the Institute of Education Class Size Study of children aged 5-7 Years