The name is absent



The second component is a measurement equation for the nonpredetermined variables and the
decision variables

dt = Sdxlxt + Sdv,χ. + Sdddt-1.                          (25)

It should be clear from equations (24) and (25) that system estimation of timeless perspec-
tive models involves the very same techniques that are used to estimate rational expectations
models. Thus, the timeless perspective raises no hurdles for estimation other than those al-
ready encountered for rational expectations models (c.f. Juillard and Pelgrin, 2007). Specifi-
cally, after introducing any necessary measurement error terms, the likelihood function can be
evaluated directly (Fuhrer and Moore, 1995; Dennis, 2004; Schmitt-Grohé and Uribe, 2007)
or be built up recursively using the Kalman filter (Hansen and Sargent, 1980), depending on
the model, and then either maximized or combined with a prior for Bayesian estimation.

4 Evaluating timeless perspective policies

An obvious alternative to timeless perspective policymaking is for the policymaker to conduct
policy with discretion. Discretion is an obvious alternative because discretionary policies are
rule-based, time-consistent, and, critically, they do not require a commitment mechanism. In
the absence of a commitment mechanism, the discretionary policymaker simply reoptimizes
period by period. Since neither policy is optimal, an essential question is whether timeless
perspective policymaking dominates discretion. This is the question I now address.

However, in order to address this question I need a method for evaluating the performance
of timeless perspective policies, an exercise that is complicated by the presence of the auxiliary
state variables. I begin by considering two possible methods. The first method is to evaluate
loss conditional on the entire (including the auxiliary) initial state vector; the second method
is to evaluate performance using unconditional loss. Using the simple new Keynesian model
to illustrate, I show that neither of these approaches is entirely satisfactory and use their
deficiencies to motivate and derive an alternative measure of policy performance.

4.1 The simple example continued

To illustrate the central issues, it is useful to return to the simple model introduced earlier.
Accordingly, I state without proof that the explicit targeting rule associated with discretionary
policymaking in that model is given by

^t + ~yt--it = θ∙                                   (26)

к σκ

10



More intriguing information

1. AN ANALYTICAL METHOD TO CALCULATE THE ERGODIC AND DIFFERENCE MATRICES OF THE DISCOUNTED MARKOV DECISION PROCESSES
2. Structural Influences on Participation Rates: A Canada-U.S. Comparison
3. The name is absent
4. The name is absent
5. Measuring Semantic Similarity by Latent Relational Analysis
6. Expectation Formation and Endogenous Fluctuations in Aggregate Demand
7. The name is absent
8. The name is absent
9. Backpropagation Artificial Neural Network To Detect Hyperthermic Seizures In Rats
10. INTERPERSONAL RELATIONS AND GROUP PROCESSES
11. The name is absent
12. A Principal Components Approach to Cross-Section Dependence in Panels
13. Spectral calibration of exponential Lévy Models [1]
14. THE CHANGING RELATIONSHIP BETWEEN FEDERAL, STATE AND LOCAL GOVERNMENTS
15. The name is absent
16. Experience, Innovation and Productivity - Empirical Evidence from Italy's Slowdown
17. The name is absent
18. Structural Conservation Practices in U.S. Corn Production: Evidence on Environmental Stewardship by Program Participants and Non-Participants
19. The name is absent
20. Social Balance Theory