Table 10. Simulating the impact on preferences of changing RHS variables
A. Equation (4), Table 4 (continued)
First Difference: Impact of high-skill when GDP per capita = $5000
Change in Probability ∣ Mean Std. Dev. [95% Conf. Interval]
dPr(protect==1) ∣ |
.0026699 |
.0012682 |
.0001494 |
.0052034 |
dPr(protect==2) ∣ |
.0103182 |
.004741 |
.0006345 |
.0194862 |
dPr(protect==3) ∣ |
.0105686 |
.0047525 |
.0006773 |
.0195221 |
dPr(protect==4) ∣ |
-.0006657 |
.0010204 |
-.0030787 |
.0010019 |
dPr(protect==5) ∣ |
-.0228909 |
.0102694 |
-.0420419 |
-.0014672 |
First Difference: Impact of high-skill when GDP per capita = $15000
Change in Probability ∣ Mean Std. Dev. [95% Conf. Interval]
dPr(protect==1) ∣ |
.0072067 |
.0009877 |
.0053957 |
.0093273 |
dPr(protect==2) ∣ |
.0263177 |
.002958 |
.0206797 |
.0324438 |
dPr(protect==3) ∣ |
.025299 |
.0026539 |
.0202207 |
.0305039 |
dPr(protect==4) ∣ |
-.0041574 |
.0021097 |
-.0083383 |
-.0003163 |
dPr(protect==5) ∣ |
-.0546661 |
.0057117 |
-.0655149 |
-.0436477 |
First Difference: Impact of high-skill when GDP per capita = $25000
Change in Probability ∣ Mean |
Std. Dev. |
[95% Conf. Interval] |
dPr(protect==1) ∣ .0127708 |
.0020405 |
.0090668 .0170057 .0330583 .0541702 .0312127 .0462664 -.019564 -.0036387 -.1006383 -.0677581 |
First Difference: Impact of national mobility | ||
Change in Probability ∣ Mean |
Std. Dev. |
[95% Conf. Interval] |
dPr(protect==1) ∣ .0001647 dPr(protect==4) ∣ -3.03e-06 dPr(protect==5) ∣ -.0015247 |
.000602 .002618 .0002122 |
-.0009862 .0013277 -.0039293 .0052194 -.004298 .0055967 -.0004342 .0004178 -.0121468 .0094165 |
First Difference: Impact of international mobility | ||
Change in Probability ∣ Mean |
Std. Dev. |
[95% Conf. Interval] |
dPr(protect==1) ∣ .0049903 dPr(protect==2) ∣ .0187507 dPr(protect==3) ∣ .0185949 dPr(protect==4) ∣ -.0021242 dPr(protect==5)∣ -.0402116 |
.0009142 |
.0032012 .0068706 .0125397 .0248353 -.0053734 .0007657 -.0528894 -.0271189 |
41