these points leads to different continuation games and allocates a considerable
rent between A and B. This makes competition particularly strong at these
states. We call these states "tipping states" because success of an advantaged
player at each of these two states "tips" the game so that victory is obtained
without further effort. A loss by the advantaged player throws the system
back into a competitive state where the player becomes disadvantaged.
Proposition 1 also shows that the allocation of a prize in a tug-of-war
leads to a seemingly peaceful outcome whenever the conflict starts in a state
other than a tipping state. This will be important for drawing conclusions
in section 3 about the efficiency properties of a tug-of-war as an allocation
mechanism.
Proposition 1 does not consider all possible parameter cases. Before turn-
ing to the remaining cases, note that the case j0 = 1 cannot emerge, as this
requires SZa < Sm^1Zs, and this contradicts Za ≥ Zb for m > 2. However,
player A’s dominance could be sufficiently large that no interior j0 exists that
has the properties defined in Proposition 1. This leads to
Proposition 2 Suppose that Smm 1 Za > SZb. Then a unique Markov perfect
equilibrium exists with vb(j) = 0 and vA(j) = SjZa for all j ∈ {1,...,m — 2},
and vA(m — 1) = Stu-1Za — SZb and vb(m — 1) = 0 at j = m — 1.
Proof. We show that the following effort choices constitute an equilib-
rium and yield the payoffs described in the proposition. Uniqueness follows
the argument in the Appendix.
Effort is a(j) = b(j) = 0 for all j ∈ Mmt∖{m — 1} and for j = m — 1 efforts
are chosen according to the following cumulative distribution functions:
Fm→(α) = ½ sf a ∈ fffA (20)
[1 for a > SZb
G ι(b) = ½ (1 — sm^zA ) for b ∈ [0’SZb] (21)
b ɪ 1 for b>SZs. ( )
Note that this behavior yields the payoffs that are characterized in Proposi-
tion 2. For states j = 1, 2,..., (m —2), A wins after j further battles, and none
of the players expends effort. This confirms vA(j) = SjZa and vb(j) = 0 for
all j = 1, ...m — 2. For j = m, the payoffs are vA(m) = 0 and vs(m) = Zb.
Finally, for j = m — 1, given the mixed strategies described by (20) and (21),
the payoffs are vA(m — 1) = Stu-1Za > SZb and vb(m — 1) = 0.
16
More intriguing information
1. Foreign Direct Investment and the Single Market2. Effects of a Sport Education Intervention on Students’ Motivational Responses in Physical Education
3. The name is absent
4. Beyond Networks? A brief response to ‘Which networks matter in education governance?’
5. Strategic monetary policy in a monetary union with non-atomistic wage setters
6. The name is absent
7. The name is absent
8. Deletion of a mycobacterial gene encoding a reductase leads to an altered cell wall containing β-oxo-mycolic acid analogues, and the accumulation of long-chain ketones related to mycolic acids
9. Social Cohesion as a Real-life Phenomenon: Exploring the Validity of the Universalist and Particularist Perspectives
10. On the estimation of hospital cost: the approach