The name is absent



Now we confirm that the effort choices in the candidate equilibrium are
indeed mutually optimal replies. For interior states
j < m 1, a deviation
b0(j) > 0 makes B win the battle, instead of A. It leads to j + 1, instead
of
j 1, but V в (j + 1) = vb (j 1) = 0 . Hence, this deviation reduces B’s
payoff by
b0(j) compared to b(j) = 0. For A, for jm 1, contestant A
reaches j = 0 along the shortest possible series of battle victories and does
not spend any effort. Any positive effort can therefore only decrease
A’s
payoff. For
j = m 1, the battle either leads to j = m where B finally
wins the prize, or to
j = m 2. The values the players attribute to reaching
these states are
Vj(m) = 0, vb(m) = Zb, and vA(m 2) = δm^2ZA and
v
b (m 2) = 0. Using the results in Hillman and Riley (1989) and Baye,
Kovenock and deVries (1996) on a complete information all-pay auction with
prizes δ'7r'
2Za0] = δ"'"'' iZa for A and 5[Zb 0] = 5Zb for B, it is
confirmed that (20) and (21) describe the unique equilibrium cumulative
distribution functions of effort for this all-pay auction. ■

Proposition 2 shows that a very strong player has a positive continuation
value regardless of the interior state in which the tug-of-war starts and wins
with probability 1 without expending effort for every interior state except
j = m 1.

So far we have ruled out the case of equality of continuation values at
interior states, and we turn to this case now which exhausts the set of possible
cases.

Proposition 3 The tug-of-war with δioZa = δ(m 7) ZbZ for some j0
{2,...(m 1)} has a unique subgame perfect equilibrium in which players
spend a(j)
= b(j) = 0 in all interior states j = j0. They choose efforts
a(j
) and b(j) at j = j0 from the same uniform distribution on the range
[0,Z]. Payoffs are Vj(j) = δ7Za  and Vb(j) = 0 for j < jo, Vj(j) = 0 and

vb(j) = δm~7Zb for j > jo and Vj(j) = Vb(j) = 0 for j = jo.

Proof. We again construct an equilibrium to demonstrate existence.
Uniqueness follows from arguments similar to those appearing in the Ap-
pendix.

In the candidate equilibrium each contestant expends zero effort at any
state
j = j0 and expends effort at j = j0 according to a draw from the
distribution

fw = ½ 1 far '∈∈Z                  (22)

1 foi ʃ > z .

17



More intriguing information

1. The name is absent
2. The name is absent
3. Does South Africa Have the Potential and Capacity to Grow at 7 Per Cent?: A Labour Market Perspective
4. THE RISE OF RURAL-TO-RURAL LABOR MARKETS IN CHINA
5. Studying How E-Markets Evaluation Can Enhance Trust in Virtual Business Communities
6. Herman Melville and the Problem of Evil
7. Influence of Mucilage Viscosity On The Globule Structure And Stability Of Certain Starch Emulsions
8. Are Public Investment Efficient in Creating Capital Stocks in Developing Countries?
9. The name is absent
10. The Challenge of Urban Regeneration in Deprived European Neighbourhoods - a Partnership Approach
11. Retirement and the Poverty of the Elderly in Portugal
12. The name is absent
13. Wirkt eine Preisregulierung nur auf den Preis?: Anmerkungen zu den Wirkungen einer Preisregulierung auf das Werbevolumen
14. Searching Threshold Inflation for India
15. The Global Dimension to Fiscal Sustainability
16. Les freins culturels à l'adoption des IFRS en Europe : une analyse du cas français
17. Short- and long-term experience in pulmonary vein segmental ostial ablation for paroxysmal atrial fibrillation*
18. Innovation in commercialization of pelagic fish: the example of "Srdela Snack" Franchise
19. Creating a 2000 IES-LFS Database in Stata
20. Income Taxation when Markets are Incomplete