Real Exchange Rate Misalignment: Prelude to Crisis?



with the fundamentals in levels, the first differences as well as first differences with up to four
period lags and four period leads were also considered. Here, for lack of space only the
coefficients of the fundamentals in levels are reported. The t-statistics are adjusted by a factor, as
recommended by Hamilton (1994, pp. 610) and Hayashi (2000, pp. 656 - 658).

2 The residuals are calculated as the differences between the observed values and the fitted
values (given by the fundamentals in levels). The critical values are from Philips and Ouliaris
(1990, Table IIc).

All of the coefficient estimates (except that of OPEN) in the final specifications are
statistically significant at 5% levels, and have the expected signs. The OPEN variable is
statistically significant at the 10% level for both countries. The TREND variable essentially
accounts for the effects of productivity growth. To the extent productivity growth takes place in
the non-traded goods sector, the real exchange rate is expected to fall. However, if productivity
increases in the traded goods sector instead, then the demand for labor in this sector increases,
wages rise, and as a result, the price of non-traded goods increases and the real exchange rate
rises (a positive Balassa-Samuelson effect). For both the countries, TREND is found to be
significant with a positive sign, thus indicating productivity growth in the traded goods sector.
With the transition economies opening to the world markets, the domestic producers of traded
goods face increased competition on the world market. The result confirms the suggestion by
Halpern and Wyplosz (1997),
inter alia, that changes in demand and productivity conditions
contributed to the real appreciations of the exchange rates in the transition economies. The
coefficient for the terms of trade, TOT, has a negative sign for both countries. This indicates that
in these countries the substitution effects are larger than the income effect of a change in the
terms of trade
. Capital flows, FLOW, is found to be statistically significant for both countries
with a positive sign. This is important since Brada (1998) ) and Drabek and Brada (1998) point
out that all the transition economies liberalized capital accounts, and this resulted in massive

26



More intriguing information

1. NATURAL RESOURCE SUPPLY CONSTRAINTS AND REGIONAL ECONOMIC ANALYSIS: A COMPUTABLE GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM APPROACH
2. Heavy Hero or Digital Dummy: multimodal player-avatar relations in FINAL FANTASY 7
3. Are Japanese bureaucrats politically stronger than farmers?: The political economy of Japan's rice set-aside program
4. Palkkaneuvottelut ja työmarkkinat Pohjoismaissa ja Euroopassa
5. Non Linear Contracting and Endogenous Buyer Power between Manufacturers and Retailers: Empirical Evidence on Food Retailing in France
6. Comparison of Optimal Control Solutions in a Labor Market Model
7. The name is absent
8. Placenta ingestion by rats enhances y- and n-opioid antinociception, but suppresses A-opioid antinociception
9. Foreword: Special Issue on Invasive Species
10. The name is absent
11. Fiscal Sustainability Across Government Tiers
12. THE MEXICAN HOG INDUSTRY: MOVING BEYOND 2003
13. The Tangible Contribution of R&D Spending Foreign-Owned Plants to a Host Region: a Plant Level Study of the Irish Manufacturing Sector (1980-1996)
14. Consumer Networks and Firm Reputation: A First Experimental Investigation
15. The name is absent
16. SME'S SUPPORT AND REGIONAL POLICY IN EU - THE NORTE-LITORAL PORTUGUESE EXPERIENCE
17. CONSIDERATIONS CONCERNING THE ROLE OF ACCOUNTING AS INFORMATIONAL SYSTEM AND ASSISTANCE OF DECISION
18. Willingness-to-Pay for Energy Conservation and Free-Ridership on Subsidization – Evidence from Germany
19. Developmental Robots - A New Paradigm
20. THE WAEA -- WHICH NICHE IN THE PROFESSION?