The optimal investment- policy17 uɪ, called “cau-
tious”, is shown in Figure 22. The target is ⅛ =
1OO,OOO.
400

Fig. 22. A cautious policy.
350
300

cautious strategy
x0=73500; Ex10=99541
250 ^.....cautious'strategy...........■'
X0=60000;Exi0=84686 : ,'∙∙4
median=86399 : :
200 -........ (.........(.........(∙
150-∙
100-∙
50-

x1-0^
∣ max expected value strategy :
∕x0=735OO)E<io=1672OO ;
'I median= 84015 : :
11111 111 I lJljijJL.JjjjjjJj-.iij-
0 0.2 0.4 0.6 0.8 1 1.2 1.4 1.6 1.8 2
x 105
The solution is intuitively explicable: if there is a
shortage of funds, or time, the manager’s actions
become risky. In other words, the policy lines get-
higher and steeper as .τo falls. Also, for the part- of
the strategy graph where it- is impossible to meet
the target- xτ by investing in the riskless asset-
only (i.c., before each line hits 0.), each policy line
representing a later time dominates the lines that
correspond to earlier times.
The usefulness of the cautious strategy for pension
fund management- can be assessed from Figure 23.
Fig. 23. A policy comparison.
Overall the cautious strategy appears an attrac-
tive portfolio management- policy. However, to use
it- for pension advertising, or for pricing the .Тю
“bond”, the objective function should reward the
manager for exceeding a target- (here, $100,000)
more than the square root- term18 .
An optimal control problem with g (ɪ (t ), и (t ), t) ≠
0 and s(X(T)) = e~eτx(T} i.c., one in which
a combination of the final wealth and the util-
ity from consumption is maximised, can also be
solved using the above approximation method.
The cautious strategy was used to manage two
initial payments x0 of $60,000 and $73,500. The
corresponding yield spreads arc represented by the
two central histograms in Figure 23. It- is easy to
see that the risk indices VaR and CVaR will be
very small for the first- outlay and virtually zero
for the second. For comparisons, the background
“back-t-o-back” histogram represents the result- of
managing the second payment- using the expected
value maximisation strategy. Oncc again we can
see that results worse than a “secure” investment
outcome ($99,215 in this ease) arc very probable.
6. CONCLUSION
A discretisation method useful for AIarkovian
approximations of finite-horizon continuous-time
stochastic optimal-control problems has been de-
scribed. An optimising algorithm has been devel-
oped (see [18] ) and applied to solve a portfolio
selection problem. For the calibrated models, an
overall agreement- between the analytical (where
obtainable) and approximating solutions was no-
ticed. However, a large variance of utility real-
isations was observed. It- was also noticed that
the variance diminished for constrained optimal
solutions.
In the example with variable volatility, no dif-
ference was reported in consumption patterns
between periods of low and high volatilities.
17Tho rest of the problem parameters are as before Lo.,
T = 10, u2 = .02, r = .05, etc.
lsFor example, (xτ - xτ)10 could be tried.
15
More intriguing information
1. The name is absent2. Popular Conceptions of Nationhood in Old and New European
3. The name is absent
4. Investment and Interest Rate Policy in the Open Economy
5. The Integration Order of Vector Autoregressive Processes
6. Pupils’ attitudes towards art teaching in primary school: an evaluation tool
7. The Social Context as a Determinant of Teacher Motivational Strategies in Physical Education
8. Effort and Performance in Public-Policy Contests
9. ROBUST CLASSIFICATION WITH CONTEXT-SENSITIVE FEATURES
10. Les freins culturels à l'adoption des IFRS en Europe : une analyse du cas français