DURABLE CONSUMPTION AS A STATUS GOOD: A STUDY OF NEOCLASSICAL CASES



(2.10a) is the first order condition for own consumption in which the agent takes the
average level of durable consumption in the economy,
C + A, as given in performing
his optimization. This is also the case in equation (2.10c), which describes the dynamics
shadow value
φ when the stock of own durable consumption goods a is chosen optimally.
Equation (2.10b) is a standard
first order condition for work effort in the neoclassical
context, while equation (2.10d) de
fines the dynamics of the shadow value μ when physical
capital
к is chosen optimally. Our specification of preferences in equations (2.3a)-(2.3b)
guarantees that the Hamiltonian (2.9) is jointly concave in the control variables c and
I
and the state variables a and к. This implies that if the limiting transversality conditions
lim
t→∞ aφe-βt = limt→∞ kμe-βt = 0 hold, then necessary conditions (2.10a)-(2.10d) are
su
fficient for optimality.

As is the usual practise in models of the type, we restrict our subsequent analysis to
symmetric equilibria in which identical agents make identical choices. This is the procedure
followed by Gal
i (1994), Persson (1995), Harbaugh (1996), Rauscher (1997b), Grossmann
(1998), Ljungqvist and Uhlig (2000), and Fisher and Hof (2000a, b), among others. In
the context of our model, we specify that the individual quantities of durable consump-
tion (current
flows and aggregate stocks) equal their average levels, i.e., c + a ≡ C + A.
Substituting this relationship into (2.10a) and combining with (2.10c), we obtain:

Uc [c + a, s (1)] + Us [C + α+ (J)] *' (1) = μ φ = (β + δ)φ - φ,       (2.11)

where the optimality conditions for work effort and capital accumulation remain un-
changed.

Using (2.11) and (2.10b), it is straightforward to calculate the following instantaneous
solutions for consumption and work e
ffort in terms of the state and costate variables:

c = c (α,μ, φ) ;     ca < 0,     cμ = -cφ < 0,                (2.12a)

I = I (k,μ);      lk > 0,      lμ > 0,

(2.12b)


where the expressions for the partial derivatives are given in the appendix. The partial



More intriguing information

1. Agricultural Policy as a Social Engineering Tool
2. THE WELFARE EFFECTS OF CONSUMING A CANCER PREVENTION DIET
3. The Institutional Determinants of Bilateral Trade Patterns
4. The Impact of Optimal Tariffs and Taxes on Agglomeration
5. Ultrametric Distance in Syntax
6. STIMULATING COOPERATION AMONG FARMERS IN A POST-SOCIALIST ECONOMY: LESSONS FROM A PUBLIC-PRIVATE MARKETING PARTNERSHIP IN POLAND
7. Long-Term Capital Movements
8. Restricted Export Flexibility and Risk Management with Options and Futures
9. Who’s afraid of critical race theory in education? a reply to Mike Cole’s ‘The color-line and the class struggle’
10. Regional differentiation in the Russian federation: A cluster-based typification
11. What should educational research do, and how should it do it? A response to “Will a clinical approach make educational research more relevant to practice” by Jacquelien Bulterman-Bos
12. The Distribution of Income of Self-employed, Entrepreneurs and Professions as Revealed from Micro Income Tax Statistics in Germany
13. Effects of red light and loud noise on the rate at which monkeys sample the sensory environment
14. The name is absent
15. The Complexity Era in Economics
16. Centre for Longitudinal Studies
17. The voluntary welfare associations in Germany: An overview
18. Changing spatial planning systems and the role of the regional government level; Comparing the Netherlands, Flanders and England
19. The name is absent
20. Measuring Semantic Similarity by Latent Relational Analysis