On s-additive robust representation of convex risk measures for unbounded financial positions in the presence of uncertainty about the market model



continuous real-valued mappings on SL1+,. The inverse mapping Φ 1 : Φ(L(Ω,F,P)) → L(Ω,F,P) may be
1

used to define the convex risk measure ρ := ρ◦ Φ 1 on X := Φ(L(Ω,F,P)) w.r.t. to the identity π on R. Notice
that Φ(
R) consists of all constant real-valued mappings on SL1+ .

Furthermore let F be the linear span of the Dirac measures δ<g> (< g >∈ SL1+ ). For any ν ∈ F there is
some < 
g >∈ L1(Ω, F, P) such that R Φ(< X >) dν = R Xg dP holds for every < X >∈ L(Ω,F, P), and
∣∣ν∣∣f := sup{∣ R Φ(< X >) dν∣ ∣ sup ∣Φ(< X >)(< g >)∣ ≤ 1} = Il g > H1. Here ∣∣∙∣∣1 denotes the Li—norm.

<g>SL1+

r

Conversely, for each < g > from L1(Ω, F, P) with arbitrary representation < g >=    λi < gi > (r ∈ N, λi R,

i=1
r

< gi >∈ SL1+ ; i = 1,...,r), we may define ν := P λiδ<gi> F which satisfies ʃ Φ(< X >) dν = ʃ Xg dP for
i=1

every < X >∈ L∞(Ω,F,P). Therefore F is complete w.r.t. the seminorm ∣∣ ∙ ∣f, and in order to apply Theorem
2.2 we have to show that the conditions (2.1), (2.2) are fulfilled for the sets
Ar := ρ-1(] — ∞, 0]) ∩ Br and
~ . . . . . . . . .

Br := {Φ(< X >) ∈ X ∣ sup   ∣Φ(< X >)(< g >)∣ ≤ r} (r > 0).

<g>SL1+

For this purpose fix r > 0. Since L(Ω, F, P) represents the norm dual of L1(Ω, F, P), the application of the
Banach-Alaoglu theorem yields that Φ
-1(Br) is σ(L(Ω, F, P), L1(Ω, F, P))—compact. This in turn implies by
construction that B
r is compact w.r.t. the topology σ (X, F) of pointwise convergence.

Moreover, by definition of Φ, the mapping φ : X → L1(Ω, F, P), Φ(< X >) →< X >, is injective, and continuous
w.r.t. σ(
X, F) and the weak topology on L1(Ω, F, P). Since the closure cl(Ar) w.r.t. σ(X, F) is even compact,
the restriction ^∣cl(A
r) : cl(Ar) → φ(d(Ar)) is a homeomorphism w.r.t. the associated relative topologies. In
particular
φ(d(Ar)) is the weak closure of φ(Ar), and hence, by Eberlein-Smulian theorem, every element is the
limit point of a sequence in
φ(Ar) w.r.t. the weak topology. Therefore each point from Cl(Ar) is the pointwise
limit of a sequence in A
r.

Now in view of Proposition 1.4 the relationships .1 ⇒ .2 ⇔ .3 are clear. The implication .3 ⇒ .1 follows from
Theorem 2.2 by the following argument. Let (X
n)n be a sequence in L(Ω, F, P) and let X ∈ L(Ω, F, P) such
that (Φ(< X
n >)n is uniformly bounded and converges pointwise to Φ(< X >). We may find a subsequence
(X
i(n))n with lim inf ρ(Xn) = lim ρ(Xi(n)). Since the P —essential sup norm on L(Ω, F, P) coincides with
n→∞        n→∞

the operator norm w.r.t. ∣∣ ∙ ∣∣1, the sequence (Xn)n is P —essentially bounded. Therefore Komlos’ subsequence
theorem (cf. [7], Lemma 1.69) guarantees a sequence (Y
n)n of convex combinations Yn from {Xi(m) | m ≥ n}
which converges P —a.s. pointwise to X and satisfies liminf ρ(X
n) ≥ liminf ρ(Yn).                             H

n→∞       n→∞

6 Some auxiliary results

Throughout this section we want to gather some technical arguments which will be often used when proving
the main results of the paper. In the following ρ denotes a convex risk measure w.r.t. π associated with the

14



More intriguing information

1. The name is absent
2. Categorial Grammar and Discourse
3. The name is absent
4. Errors in recorded security prices and the turn-of-the year effect
5. ISO 9000 -- A MARKETING TOOL FOR U.S. AGRIBUSINESS
6. Estimating the Technology of Cognitive and Noncognitive Skill Formation
7. The name is absent
8. TINKERING WITH VALUATION ESTIMATES: IS THERE A FUTURE FOR WILLINGNESS TO ACCEPT MEASURES?
9. The name is absent
10. The name is absent