4.2 The representative agent’s optimal decisions
Again, it is easy to check that a generalized version of Robinson Crusoe’s value function
and of the representative agent’s value function V found in Bethmann (2002) satisfies
the Bellman equation (27) and the first order necessary conditions (28) and (29) simul-
taneously:
V (kt, ht; ha,t) = ψ + ψB ln B + ΨA ln At + ψk ln kt + ψh ln ht + ψha ln ha,t, (34)
where the φi’s, with i ∈ {k, h, ha,B,A}, are defined as follows3:
kk := 1-αβ , kh := (1-β)(1-αβ), Ψha := (1-β)Y1-αβ),
_ (1-α+γ)β _ 1
ψB := (1-β)2(1-αβ) , 7A := (1-ρβ)(1-αβ) ∙
The optimal controls implied by V are the following:
ct = (1 — αβ) yt and ut = β+wT(1(--β). (35)
If the government sets τw and τr equal to 1, these results correspond exactly to the
deterministic case examined in Bethmann (2002)∙ V implies a constant allocation of
human capital between the two production sectors, i∙e∙ the evolution of the average
stock of human capital ha does not enter the first-order necessary condition for ut in (35)∙
Hence, there is no linkage between the representative agent’s decision and the economy-
wide average decision∙ Therefore the solution strategy of determining the evolution of the
agent’s stock of capital and then exploiting the symmetry condition (6) is equivalent to
the strategy of finding a fixed point where the representative agent’s policy rules coincide
with the economy-wide average decisions∙ Hence, the equation:
h . . B — B______β______h .
ha,t+1 B β+τw(1-β) ha,t.
determines the path of the economy-wide average level of human capital in the decen-
tralized economy∙ Together with the agent’s optimal controls, this result implies that the
Euler equations (31) and (32) and the transversality conditions (33) are met∙
4.3 The government’s optimal policy
The government wants to reach the social planner’s solution by taxing, respectively
subsidizing the agent’s factor compensations∙ Note that the absence ofτr in the first order
conditions (35) implies that the planner’s solution can be reached by simply requiring ut
to be socially optimal∙ On the other hand, assumption (10) requires that the state has
to ensure that its budget is balanced in each period∙ These two requirements lead us to
the following two conditions:
(1-α)(1-β) τw (1-β)
1-α+βY β+τw (1-β)
and (τr - 1) α = (1 - τw) (1 - α) . (36)
This implies the following optimal values of τw and τr :
Tw = 1-α+γ and
3The constant is given by: φ ≡ ln[1-βj'β +
(1-α) ln[τw] _ (1-α+βγ) ln[β+τm (1-β)]
(1-αβ)(1-β) (1-αβ)(1-β)2 '
_ α-α2+γ
Tr (1-α+γ)α .
(1-α)ln[1-β] . αβ ln α . (1-αβ+γ)β ln β l
(1-β)(1-αβ) + (1-β)(1-αβ) + (1-β)2(1-αβ) +
More intriguing information
1. Palkkaneuvottelut ja työmarkkinat Pohjoismaissa ja Euroopassa2. The name is absent
3. Applications of Evolutionary Economic Geography
4. EFFICIENCY LOSS AND TRADABLE PERMITS
5. The name is absent
6. A Duality Approach to Testing the Economic Behaviour of Dairy-Marketing Co-operatives: The Case of Ireland
7. Migrating Football Players, Transfer Fees and Migration Controls
8. An Intertemporal Benchmark Model for Turkey’s Current Account
9. Forecasting Financial Crises and Contagion in Asia using Dynamic Factor Analysis
10. Cyclical Changes in Short-Run Earnings Mobility in Canada, 1982-1996