proposition 3.1.1 and theorem 4.1 we have:
* - st
-t (1 - α)β ;
substituting st* using proposition 5.1 we obtain:
-* = 1 (1 - β)-*Le ;
t (1 - α)β Nt - Le
and simplifying wt* equation 54 becomes:
Lte
(1 - α)β N
(1 - α)β +(1 - β) t;
that is,
ut =
1 - β
1 - αβ
From ( 22) we have:
Lte
1-α
cAt α wt-1 Le-1
(53)
(54)
(55)
(56)
(57)
1-α
Substituting ( 55) in ( 57), if there is unemployment in period t - 1 solving for
wt* we obtain:
* 4l-α∕1 vcw*-1Nt-1 1a 4l-α∕1 v cw*-1 lα ∕κcλ
wt = cAt (1 - α)[----N----] = At (1 - α)[(1 + n) ] . (58)
Diving ( 58) by At we obtain:
wt--1
w* c ~ï---
— = (1 - α)[-----A—----]a. (59)
At ( )[(1 + n)(1+ g)] ( )
Ifwe call at the equilibrium wage per unit of efficient labor ω*, that is, ω* = A-
equation ( 59) becomes:
ω* = (1 - α)[ ---——----]a. (60)
t ( )[(1 + n)(1+ g)] ()
Solving ( 60) for ωL* -R when ωt* = ωt*-l = ωL* -R we obtain :
ωL в = (1 - α)1-α (-------—:-------)1-α . (61)
l-r ( ) ((1 + n)(1 + g)) ()
It is easy to check, drawing the phase diagram that the wage per unit of efficient
labour converges to ωL* -R. From ( 22) we have in period zero
e
L0
1-α
A0 α Ko ,
[ twl ] α ;
l-α
(62)
22
More intriguing information
1. Second Order Filter Distribution Approximations for Financial Time Series with Extreme Outlier2. The name is absent
3. Do imputed education histories provide satisfactory results in fertility analysis in the Western German context?
4. O funcionalismo de Sellars: uma pesquisa histδrica
5. Are combination forecasts of S&P 500 volatility statistically superior?
6. Structural Breakpoints in Volatility in International Markets
7. Structural Influences on Participation Rates: A Canada-U.S. Comparison
8. Wounds and reinscriptions: schools, sexualities and performative subjects
9. The name is absent
10. The name is absent