Constrained School Choice



We distinguish among three cases for the priority ordering fs2 of school s2 with respect
to students i
1, i2, and i3: (i) fs2 (i2) < fs2 (i3) < fs2 (i1), (ii) fs2 (i3) < fs2 (i2) < fs2 (i1),
and (iii) f
s2 (i3) < fs2 (i1) < fs2 (i2). One easily verifies that in each of the cases (i), (ii),
and (iii), the unique stable matching for
P is μ* = γ(P) with μ*(i1) = s1, μ*(i3) = s2,
and μ*(i2) = i2.

Consider Q Q(k)I defined by Qi2 := 0 and Qi := Pi for all i Ii2. One easily
verifies that in each of the cases (i), (ii), and (iii), γ(Q)(i
1) = s2 and γ(Q)(i3) = s1. So,
γ (Q) = μ
*, and hence γ(Q) S (P ). Finally, one easily verifies that Q Eγ (P, k).     

A mechanism is non bossy if no student can maintain his allotment and cause a change
in the other students’ allotments by reporting different preferences.

Definition A.4 Non Bossy Mechanism (Satterthwaite and Sonnenschein, 1981)
A mechanism
φ is non bossy if for all i I, Qi, Qi Q, and Q-i QI\i, φ(Q'i, Q-i)(i) =
φ(Qi,Q-i)(i) implies φ(Q'i,Q-i) = φ(Qi,Q-i).                                           

Lemma A.5 Let f be an Ergin-acyclic priority structure. Then, γ is non bossy.

Proof Follows from Ergin’s (2002) Theorem 1, (iv) (iii) and proof of (iii) (ii).

Lemma A.6 Let f be an Ergin-acyclic priority structure. Let 2 k m. Then, for any
school choice problem
P all equilibrium outcomes in the game Γγ (P, k) are stable, i.e., for
all
Q Eγ(P, k), γ(Q) S(P).

Proof Suppose to the contrary that Q Eγ(P, k) but γ(Q) S(P). So, by Lemma A.2,
there are i, j
I, i = j and s S with γ(Q)(j) = s, sPiγ(Q)(i), and fs(i) < fs(j).

Since γ is strategy-proof in the unconstrained setting (i.e., when the quota equals m,
the number of schools), γ(P
i,Q-i)Riγ(Qi, Q-i). Let Qi := γ(Pi,Q-i)(i). Clearly, Qi
Q
(k). By Lemma A.1, γ(Qi,Q-i)(i) = γ(Pi,Q-i)(i). Hence, γ(Qi, Q-i)Riγ(Qi, Q-i).
If γ(Q
i,Q-i)Piγ(Qi,Q-i), then Q Eγ(P, k), a contradiction. Hence, γ(Qi,Q-i)(i) =
γ(Q
i,Q-i)(i).

By Lemma A.5, γ is non bossy. Hence, γ(Pi, Q-i) = γ(Qi, Q-i) = γ(Q). In particular,
γ(P
i, Q-i)(j) = γ(Q)(j) = s. Since sPiγ(Q)(i) = γ(Pi, Q-i)(i), student i has justified
envy at γ (P
i, Q-i), contradicting γ (Pi, Q-i) S (Pi, Q-i). Hence, γ(Q) S (P ).        

Proof of Theorem 6.5 Proposition 6.1 implies that the game Γγ(P, 1) = Γβ(P, 1)
implements S(P) in Nash equilibria,
i.e., S(P) = Oγ(P, 1). Theorem 5.3 implies that
S (P ) =
Oγ (P, 1) Oγ (P, k). Now Lemmas A.3 and A.6 complete the proof.         

30



More intriguing information

1. Cardiac Arrhythmia and Geomagnetic Activity
2. The urban sprawl dynamics: does a neural network understand the spatial logic better than a cellular automata?
3. BUSINESS SUCCESS: WHAT FACTORS REALLY MATTER?
4. Update to a program for saving a model fit as a dataset
5. Methods for the thematic synthesis of qualitative research in systematic reviews
6. FUTURE TRADE RESEARCH AREAS THAT MATTER TO DEVELOPING COUNTRY POLICYMAKERS
7. Sectoral specialisation in the EU a macroeconomic perspective
8. Analyse des verbraucherorientierten Qualitätsurteils mittels assoziativer Verfahren am Beispiel von Schweinefleisch und Kartoffeln
9. Asymmetric transfer of the dynamic motion aftereffect between first- and second-order cues and among different second-order cues
10. The Advantage of Cooperatives under Asymmetric Cost Information
11. Globalization, Redistribution, and the Composition of Public Education Expenditures
12. Une Classe de Concepts
13. Gender stereotyping and wage discrimination among Italian graduates
14. Explaining Growth in Dutch Agriculture: Prices, Public R&D, and Technological Change
15. AN EXPLORATION OF THE NEED FOR AND COST OF SELECTED TRADE FACILITATION MEASURES IN ASIA AND THE PACIFIC IN THE CONTEXT OF THE WTO NEGOTIATIONS
16. Gender and headship in the twenty-first century
17. Large-N and Large-T Properties of Panel Data Estimators and the Hausman Test
18. Industrial districts, innovation and I-district effect: territory or industrial specialization?
19. DISCUSSION: POLICY CONSIDERATIONS OF EMERGING INFORMATION TECHNOLOGIES
20. The name is absent