where σ02=2E{θ2(1-θ)2f (zt)}{∫K2(u)du} under the null.
Step 2. Conditional asymptotic equivalence:
Suppose that both Thm/2(JT-JTU) =op(1) and Thm/2(JT-JTU) =op(1).
Then Thm/2(Jt - JT ) = op (1) . (A.6)
Step 3. Asymptotic equivalence:
Thm/2(JT-JTU) =op(1) and Thm/2(JT-JTL) =op(1). (A.7)
The combination of Steps 1-3 yields Theorem 1 (i).
Step 1: Asymptotic normality.
Since JT is a degenerate U-statistic of order 2, the result follows from Lemma 2.
□
Step 2: Conditional asymptotic equivalence.
The proof of Step 2 is motivated by the technique of Hardle and Stoker (1989) which was
used in treating trimming indicator function asymptotically. Suppose that the following two
statements hold.
Thm/2(JT-JTU)=op(1) and (A.8)
Thm/2(JT-JTL)=op(1) (A.9)
Denote CT as an upper bound consistent with the uniform convergence rate of the
nonparametric estimator of conditional quantile given in equation (13). Suppose that
sup ∣ qθ (x) - qθ (x)l≤ Ct . (A.10)
If inequality (A.3) holds, then the following statements also hold:
{ Qθ(x) > yt + CT } ⊂ { (Qθ(x) > yt } ⊂ { Qθ(x) > yt -CT }, (A.11-1)
1( Qθ (x) > yt + CT ) ≤ 1( (Qθ (x) > yt ) ≤ 1( Qθ (x) > yt - CT ), (A.11-2)
Jtu ≤ Jt ≤ Jtl , and (A.11-3)
| Thm/2(Jt - Jt)| ≤ max {∣Thm/2(Jt - Jtu)| , |Thm/2(Jt - Jtl)| } (A. 11-4)
12
More intriguing information
1. Wettbewerbs- und Industriepolitik - EU-Integration als Dritter Weg?2. ISO 9000 -- A MARKETING TOOL FOR U.S. AGRIBUSINESS
3. The name is absent
4. Long-Term Capital Movements
5. Kharaj and land proprietary right in the sixteenth century: An example of law and economics
6. The Mathematical Components of Engineering
7. The name is absent
8. DISCUSSION: ASSESSING STRUCTURAL CHANGE IN THE DEMAND FOR FOOD COMMODITIES
9. Comparative study of hatching rates of African catfish (Clarias gariepinus Burchell 1822) eggs on different substrates
10. The name is absent