Using (A.10) and (A.11-4), we have the following inequality;
Pr[∖Thml( J - JT)| > δ I sup∖Q,(x)-Qθ(x)≤C}
≤ Pr{ max { ∖Thm2(J -J„,)| , ∖TW'∖Jt - Jtl)| } > δ I sup∖Qβ(x)-Q(x)∖≤CT}
, for all δ > 0 . (A.12)
Invoking Lemma 1 and condition A2(iii), we have
Pr{ sup∖ Qθ(x)-Qθ(x)∖≤Ct} → 1 as T → ∞ . (A.13)
By (A.8) and (A.9), as T → ∞, we have
Pr{ max { ∖Thm/2(Jt - Jtu)∖ , ∖Thm/2(Jt - Jtl)∖ } > δ } → 0, for all δ > 0.
(A.14)
Therefore, as T → ∞,
the L.H.S. of the inequality (A.12) - Pr {∖ Thm/2(Jt - Jt )∖ > δ } → 0 and
the L.H.S. of the inequality (A.12) → 0 .
In summary, we have that if both Thm/2(JT-JTU) =op(1) and Thm/2(JT-JTU) =op(1),
then Thm/2(^Jt - Jt ) = op (1). □
Step 3: Asymptotic equivalence.
In the remaining proof, we focus on showing that Thm/2(JT-JTU) =op(1), with the proof
of Thm/2(JT-JTL) =op(1) being treated similarly. The proof of Step 3 is close in lines
with the proof in Zheng (1998). Denote
HT(s,t,g)≡Kts{1(yt≤g(xt))-,}{1(ys≤g(xs))-,} and (A.15)
J[g]≡
1
T (T -1) hm
T
∑
t=1
T
∑HT(s,t,g).
s≠t
(A.16)
Then we have JT ≡ J[Q,] and JTU ≡ J[Q, -CT]. We decompose HT (s,t, g) into
three parts;
HT(s,t,g)=Kts{1(yt≤g(xt))-F(g(xt)∖zt)}{1(ys≤g(xs))-F(g(xs)∖zs)}
13
More intriguing information
1. Income Mobility of Owners of Small Businesses when Boundaries between Occupations are Vague2. Trade Openness and Volatility
3. Handling the measurement error problem by means of panel data: Moment methods applied on firm data
4. The InnoRegio-program: a new way to promote regional innovation networks - empirical results of the complementary research -
5. Optimal Private and Public Harvesting under Spatial and Temporal Interdependence
6. THE INTERNATIONAL OUTLOOK FOR U.S. TOBACCO
7. The WTO and the Cartagena Protocol: International Policy Coordination or Conflict?
8. FOREIGN AGRICULTURAL SERVICE PROGRAMS AND FOREIGN RELATIONS
9. Opciones de política económica en el Perú 2011-2015
10. Antidote Stocking at Hospitals in North Palestine