(A5)
^∑-L=0 =μι ∙ δ (1 - t) ∙t ∙
∂s

- μ1 ∙ δ∙ T ∙ t ∙

dF ( w ) + ( μ - μ) ∙ δ∙T ∙

μι ∙t ∙

dF(w) + (μ -μ1)∙

dF ( w ).
dF (w ) - ( μ - μ1) ∙ δ∙(l-1 ) ∙

w
dF ( w )
dF ( w )
We need to prove that the sign of the derivative in (A5) is negative. We first turn to
further simplify the expression on the right-hand side of (A5). Consider the following
optimization problem, where an individual, given some labor/leisure choice, l, is
choosing how to allocate the net income across consumption good, c, and charitable
contribution, z. Formulating the Lagrangean yields:
(A6) L(w, l, t,τ, s) ≡ max[u(c) +v(z)+ν∙ [(1- t)∙w ∙ (1 -l)+ T- c- (1 +s)∙ z]],
where ν denotes the Lagrange multiplier. Now consider a small change in the tax
system around the optimal linear labor income tax system (set for s=0), which is
defined as follows: ds = ∆,dt = -∆ ∙δ∙ (1 -t) and dT = ∆∙ δ∙ T , where ∆ > 0 and is
arbitrarily small. Fully differentiating the Lagrangean in (A6), using the envelope
theorem, then yields:
(A7) dL∖,=o,,T =∆∙v[-z+ δ∙[(1 -1 ) ∙ w ∙ (1 -1 ) + T ]] = 0,
where the last equality holds for any 1, by virtue of the homotheticity [see (A4)] and
the separability assumptions. It follows that the optimal labor/leisure choice of an
individual of ability w (for all w) is unaffected by the suggested small perturbation in
the tax system around the optimum. Thus, for all w, it follows that:
(A8) - δ∙(1 -1 )∙dw +dw + δ∙T.≡1*w* = 0.
∂t ∂s ∂T
23
More intriguing information
1. The name is absent2. Psychological Aspects of Market Crashes
3. The name is absent
4. The Complexity Era in Economics
5. The name is absent
6. Multiple Arrhythmogenic Substrate for Tachycardia in a
7. Fertility in Developing Countries
8. The name is absent
9. The name is absent
10. Washington Irving and the Knickerbocker Group